System handlu wielostronnego w globalnym zarządzaniu
Wzrostające się mocarstwa w globalnym systemie handlowym Chiny i negocjacje handlowe w regionie mega-regionalnym Pobierz ten artykuł w formacie PDF W tym artykule omówiono rolę rosnących uprawnień w globalnym systemie handlu w ramach Światowej Organizacji Handlu (WTO) i poza WTO. Analizuje pojawienie się dwustronnych i (mega-regionalnych porozumień), takich jak partnerstwo transatlantyckie (TPP) i transatlantyckie partnerstwo na rzecz handlu i inwestycji (TTIP) oraz ich konsekwencje dla globalnego zarządzania międzynarodowym handlem. Analizuje, jak Chiny i inne mocarstwa reagują na zmieniający się krajobraz zarządzania handlem i badają wpływ na rozwijające się i wschodzące gospodarki. Zagwarantowanie przyszłości globalnego systemu handlu, zwłaszcza WTO jako forum negocjacji wielostronnych wymaga reformy. Artykuł ocenia obecną nierówność instytucjonalną globalnego systemu handlowego i twierdzi, że status quo służy ograniczeniu zmian w ramach WTO. Należy również zbadać obecne instytucjonalne ustanowienie globalnego systemu handlowego poza WTO. Ponadto artykuł podkreśla, że grupa G20 może odegrać kluczową rolę w WTO i reformę globalnego systemu handlu. Wprowadzenie Podczas chińskiej prezydencji grupy 20 (G20) w 2018 r. Międzynarodowy handel i inwestycje odgrywały znaczącą rolę. Znaczenie międzynarodowego handlu i inwestycji dla grupy G20 ujawniły się podczas prezydencji chińskiej G20, szczególnie w oświadczeniu ministrów handlu wydanym w lipcu 2018 r. Oraz podczas szczytu w G20 w Hangzhou we wrześniu 2018 r. Handel zagraniczny był od pierwszego szczytu G20, od pierwszego lider szczytu odbył się w listopadzie 2008 r. podczas światowego kryzysu finansowego i gospodarczego oraz fazy silnie zakontraktowanego handlu światowego. Przypominając, że kryzys gospodarczy po roku 1929 pogłębia się i przedłuża fale środków protekcjonistycznych, kraje G20 zobowiązały się nie stawić żadnych nowych przeszkód w handlu międzynarodowym. Zobowiązanie do pomyślnego zakończenia dauhańskiej agendy rozwoju (runda dauhańska), wielostronnych negocjacji prowadzonych pod auspicjami Światowej Organizacji Handlu (WTO), stanowi część standardowego repertuaru deklaracji szczytu G20. Jednakże szczyt G20 nie zwrócił większej uwagi na reformę globalnego systemu handlu: Deklaracje zawierają zazwyczaj niewiele opracowane zobowiązania do wzmocnienia wielostronnego systemu handlu i oświadczenia o dwustronnych i regionalnych i wielostronnych porozumieniach handlowych uzupełniających i zgodnych z zasadami WTO. Pomimo tego, że od czasu ostatniego spotkania ministerialnego WTO w Nairobi w grudniu 2018 r. Przyszłość rundy dauhańskiej i wielostronnych negocjacji w ramach WTO są niepewne niż kiedykolwiek. Zakwestionowany imperatywem w celu znalezienia konsensu, państwa członkowskie WTO nie zdążyły zakończyć negocjacji dauhańskiej po ponad piętnastu latach. W 2018 r. Ważne państwa członkowskie, w szczególności Stany Zjednoczone Ameryki (USA), zadeklarowały się za zakończeniem rundy dauhańskiej. Jednak wiele krajów wschodzących i rozwijających się nalega, aby były kontynuowane. W reakcji na postępy poczynione przez Doha Rundy, główne uprawnienia handlowe, prowadzone przez USA i Unię Europejską (UE), coraz częściej negocjują dwustronne i regionalne umowy handlowe. Aby zagwarantować przyszłość globalnego systemu handlowego, w szczególności przyszłość WTO jako forum negocjacji wielostronnych, należy rozważyć opcje reform. Każda reforma musi również uwzględniać Agendę 2030 na rzecz Zrównoważonego Rozwoju i 17 Zrównoważonego Rozwoju (SDG), którą przyjęto przez wszystkie państwa członkowskie ONZ (ONZ) w 2018 r. SDG wymagają uniwersalnego, opartego na zasadach zasady , otwartego, niedyskryminującego i sprawiedliwego wielostronnego systemu handlowego. Ale taki system wywiera coraz większe naciski z grzybowych umów o wolnym handlu. Mega-regionalne negocjacje handlowe W ostatnim czasie stały się coraz ważniejsze partnerstwa głęboko integracyjne między krajami lub regionami o dużym znaczeniu handlu światowego. Jednak Chiny i inne mocarstwa nie należą do partnerów negocjacyjnych. Umowy o zasięgu regionalnym, takie jak partnerstwo transeuropejskie (TPP), podpisane w lutym 2018 r. Przez USA i 11 innych państw z regionu Pacyfiku oraz Transatlantyckie Partnerstwo na rzecz Handlu i Inwestycji (TTIP), które Stany Zjednoczone i UE prowadzą negocjacje, obejmują ogromne udziały globalnych handlu i inwestycji oraz dążyć do uczynienia czegoś więcej niż obniżenia taryf. Dążą również do uregulowania takich kwestii, jak konkurencja, inwestycje i standardy. Zarówno TTIP, jak i TPP odzwierciedlają interesy gospodarcze i są wywoływane przez geopolityczne i strategiczne rozumowanie, szczególnie w odniesieniu do Chin i próbę zatrzymania rosnącej potęgi. Co mega-regionalne porozumienia handlowe implikują do globalnego sprawowania rządów w handlu międzynarodowym, szczególnie z perspektywy rosnących sił i krajów rozwijających się Głęboka rola, jaką odgrywają w tym kontekście G20 Od ponad półwiecza instytucje światowej struktury zarządzania gospodarczego, w tym Ogólne porozumienie w sprawie taryf celnych i handlu (GATT) i WTO, były zdominowane przez Stany Zjednoczone i inne zaawansowane uprzemysłowione państwa (Gilpin 1987 Ruggie 1996). Kraje rozwijające się nie były potężnymi podmiotami w globalnym zarządzaniu. Teraz jednak kraje rozwijające się, takie jak Chiny, Indie i Brazylia (Beeson Bell, 2009, Hurley, 2006, Margulis, Porter 2017 Mittelman 2017, Stephen 2017 Young 2017) są wyzwaniem dla dominacji dawnych mocarstw. Czy rosnące moce, takie jak Chiny, wspierają alternatywne i bardziej słuszne podejście do gospodarki światowej (Hardt amp Negri 2000 Pieterse 2000 Evans 2008 Strange 2017) W tym artykule omówiono, w jaki sposób potęgi rosnące i kraje rozwijające się napotykają instytucjonalne nierówności w globalnym systemie handlu , czyli charakterystyk instytucji międzynarodowych, które systematycznie przywilejów nad potężnymi państwami (Fehl 2017). Badano pojęcie nierówności instytucjonalnych w WTO i zbadano, w jakim stopniu dwustronne i (mega) regionalne porozumienia handlowe kwestionują WTO jako wielostronne forum decyzyjne dotyczące globalnych reguł handlowych, jak mega-regionale pojawiają się w odpowiedzi na władzę zmiany w globalnym zarządzaniu gospodarką, a także, w jaki sposób rosnące uprawnienia reagują na zmieniający się krajobraz zarządzania rynkiem. W artykule zbadano również rolę roli mocarstw w globalnym systemie handlu, biorąc pod uwagę trwający etap procesu instytucjonalnego podziału warstw i zakupów na forum, a także wskazania bardziej istotnej zmiany systemu. W trakcie zakupów w forum shopper strategicznie wybiera miejsce, w którym można uzyskać pozytywną decyzję dotyczącą określonego problemu (Drezner 2009) w przesunięciu reżimu, aktorzy redefiniują większy kontekst polityczny, aby ostatecznie zmienić formę reguł (Alter AMUNIER 2009). W niniejszym artykule stwierdzono, że niektórzy członkowie WTO, dominujący, korzystają z obecnego procesu nakładania warstw, zakupów i przesuwania. Mechanizmy te, jak stwierdzono w niniejszym dokumencie, stały się znacznie bardziej istotne z powodu pojawienia się mega-regionalnych porozumień handlowych. Artykuł pokazuje, że analizując, w jaki sposób instytucjonalny status quo ogranicza zmiany instytucjonalne w ramach WTO, sytuacja poza tym wielostronnym forum również musi zostać rozwiązana. Ponieważ stare mocarstwa mają znacznie większe możliwości angażowania się w strategie międzyorganizacyjne, takie jak zakupy na forum (Drezner 2009) i przesunięcie reżimu (Alter AMUNIER 2009), mogą nacisnąć kraje, które nie mogą zmienić kształtu systemu, a tym samym mniej atrakcyjne na zewnątrz opcji poza WTO. Należy przeanalizować zachowanie podmiotów w poszczególnych organizacjach, takich jak WTO, jak również szerszy kontekst instytucjonalny, który może wiązać się z innymi mechanizmami organizacyjnymi w celu zwiększenia, zrównoważenia lub zmniejszenia nierówności. W dalszej części artykułu omówiono rolę wzrastających uprawnień w WTO i zbadano powstawanie dwustronnych i (mega-regionalnych porozumień) oraz konsekwencje dla globalnego zarządzania handlem międzynarodowym, koncentrując się na tym, jak rosnące potęgi reagują na zmieniający się krajobraz zarządzania handlem i reperkusji dla gospodarek rozwijających się i gospodarek wschodzących. Rosnące potęgi w Światowej Organizacji Handlu W ramach WTO umowy są formalnie osiągane na zasadzie konsensusu, co sprawia, że system GATTWTO wydaje się znacząco egalitarny w porównaniu z systemami głosowania w zależności od wagi gospodarczej w MFW i Banku Światowym. Jednak w większości przypadków system GATTWTO był zdominowany przez Stany Zjednoczone i inne potężne pod względem gospodarczym kraje: Najważniejsze negocjacje odbywają się na nieformalnych spotkaniach elitarnego kręgu państw. Przez długi czas, dobrze do rundy dauhańskiej, która rozpoczęła się w 2001 r., Tradycyjne potęgi zdołały utrzymać rosnące potęgi niepokój ich hierarchii, na przykład twierdząc, że nowa runda negocjacji byłaby etapem rozwoju, ale nie kwestionuje, czy duże powstanie gospodarki gospodarcze, takie jak Chiny, Indie i Brazylia, powinny być dalej rozwijane. W rundy dauhańskiej tradycyjnie dominujące uprawnienia zaczęły być bardziej otwarte na pomysł zmiany starej hierarchii. Zmiany zostały przyspieszone, gdy przed ministrem Cancun w 2003 r. UE i USA złożyły wspólny wniosek w sprawie rolnictwa, który wywołał silną opozycję z rozwijającymi się i wschodzącymi gospodarkami, i zachęcił Brazylię i Indie do współpracy. Dwa kraje utworzyły dużą koalicję rozwijających się i wschodzących gospodarek grupę 20 w WTO (G20-T), która pomogła pokonać propozycje USA i UE w Cancun i destabilizować tradycyjną strukturę władzy w ramach WTO (np. Looney 2004 Baldwin 2006 Clapp 2006 Hurrell amp Narlikar 2006 Evenett 2007 Grant 2007 Ruiz-Diaz 2005 Hopewell 2018). Pod kierownictwem Brazylii i Indii G20-T przekształciła instytucjonalne nierówności w ramach WTO. Po Cancun stary wewnętrzny krąg Quad (USA, UE, Japonia i Kanada) został zastąpiony nowym, wewnętrznym kręgiem, obejmującym nie tylko USA i UE, ale również Brazylię i Indie, a później również Chiny, zmieniając tym samym negocjowanie hierarchii. W różnych etapach negocjacji w ramach WTO w krajach słabiej rozwiniętych również pojawiły się wyraźne wypowiedzi. Podczas gdy Brazylia i Indie weszły do wewnętrznego kręgu WTO po 2003 r., Chiny, które przystąpiły do WTO w 2001 r., Miały niski kluczowy profil negocjacji. Następnie, w 2008 roku, został zaproszony do przyłączenia się do wewnętrznego kręgu (Hopewell 2018). Wzrostowi statusu Chin w WTO i innych dziedzinach globalnego sprawowania rządów w znacznej mierze zależało od rosnącej jego koniunktury gospodarczej (Ikenberry 2008 Babies 2017 Beeson 2009 Breslin 2017 Hung 2009 Subramanian 2017 Wang amp French 2017): jest to druga największa gospodarka świata i światowy eksporter towarów. Jednakże rosnące uprawnienia nie zostały dopuszczone do kręgu wewnętrznego, a nierównomierne nierówności w ramach WTO nie były podważane jedynie z powodu coraz bardziej sprawiedliwego podziału władzy gospodarczej: Brazylia i Indie, które nie są tak ciężkie jak Chiny, mogły wzrosnąć z powodu ich mobilizacji i kierownictwu koalicji rozwijających się i wschodzących gospodarek w pierwszych latach rundy dauhańskiej (Hopewell 2018). Dzięki budowaniu udanych koalicji Brazylia i Indie stały się pierwszymi krajami zdolnymi do podważania tradycyjnych uprawnień, odwrócenia starej struktury władzy i pojawienia się w kluczowym, nowym podmiotom w WTO. Koalice są jednak mniej stabilne i skuteczne niż ekonomiczne. Analiza najnowszych zmian w globalnym systemie handlowym poza WTO wskazuje, że nie można zaprzeczyć, jaka jest rola czynników ekonomicznych oraz że status instytucjonalny stymuluje rosnące wysiłki zmierzające do promowania ich zmieniających się pozycji energetycznych i normatywnych roszczeń dotyczących przyszłego projektu wielostronnego systemu handlu . Z biegiem lat koalicja G20-T była napięta, zwłaszcza przed rokiem ministrów WTO w Nairobi w 2018 r. W Nairobi kraje uprzemysłowione chciały przedwcześnie zakończyć rundę dauhańską lub, alternatywnie, rozszerzyć obszar Rundów, włączając ich nowe kwestie będące przedmiotem zainteresowania, w tym polityka dotycząca handlu elektronicznego, pracy, środowiska i konkurencji, które kraje rozwijające się sprzeciwiają, obawiając się, że wysokie normy mogą działać jako bariery pozataryfowe, powodując ich eksport. Podczas ostatniej nocy ministrów w Nairobi na spotkaniu w wewnętrznym kręgu krajów negocjujących Indie i Chiny walczyły o jasny język, potwierdzając kontynuację negocjacji z Doha. W trakcie negocjacji w maratonie Indie najwyraźniej ustępowały, podczas gdy USA i UE z Brazylią udało się uzyskać istotne porozumienie w sprawie wyeliminowania subsydiów rolnych na wywóz, które wiele osób uznało za kamień milowy. Umowa nie pomogła Indiasowi zaprosić do określonego czasu w programach składek publicznych i specjalnego mechanizmu zabezpieczeń, który pozwoliłby na wprowadzenie taryf w przypadku wzrostu importu. Indie zostały zepchnięte w ramach WTO i G20-T, a Brazylia i Indias raz zdecydowanie udało się koalicji rozbił się. Dlaczego koalicja G20-T nie powiodła się, a wraz z nią zdolność wzrastających uprawnień, takich jak Brazylia i Indie oraz kraje rozwijające się, aby kwestionować nierówność w ramach WTO, Brazylia i Indie były w dużym stopniu zależne od poparcia innych państw. Obie strony nie zgodziły się także na dyskurs rozwojowy, a Indie nawiązują do problemów rozwojowych ubogich w krajach przywożących netto żywności i Brazylii, koncentrując się na eksporterach netto. Innym źródłem niestabilności dla mocarstw i krajów rozwijających się jest to, że stare uprawnienia mają lepsze opcje poza granicami WTO. W miarę możliwości system multilateralny stawał się coraz bardziej nierówny w pierwszych dziesięcioleciach istnienia, a kraje Quad opracowujące hierarchiczny porządek państw i tendencje do wyłączności. Zwłaszcza po zakończeniu Rundy Urugwajskiej w negocjacjach handlowych i podczas rundy dauhańskiej podjęto starania, aby lepiej uwzględnić kraje wschodzące i rozwijające się w procesie ustalania porządku obrad i negocjacji, zmniejszając nierówność proceduralną. W ramach WTO, tak jak w kontekście innych instytucji międzynarodowych, są kwestie ideologiczne i materialne (Fehl 2017), i wydaje się, że przyczyniają się do mniejszej nierówności w WTO w czasie. Wymagania normatywne zwykle powodują równość w stosunku do nierówności. Niedawne globalne zmiany gospodarcze i wzrost nowych uprawnień zmniejszyły nierówność w podziale potencjału gospodarczego, co z kolei mogłoby zwiększyć równość, zarówno formalnie, jak i nieformalnie. Jednakże, jak pokazują kolejne sekcje, perspektywy mniejszej nierówności instytucjonalnej w globalnym systemie handlu mają mniejsze wyraźne implikacje, niż się spodziewano. Pieczenie umów o wolnym handlu Badanie całego systemu handlowego, w tym umów o wolnym handlu, które grzybują poza reżimem wielostronnym, podkreśla znaczenie instytucjonalnego status quo formalnej równości w WTO. Równość w formułowaniu decyzji w zgodzie z konsensusem przyczynia się do utrudnień i ogranicza wysiłki szerszego członkostwa w WTO w celu skutecznego promowania ich pozycji energetycznych i normatywnych wniosków o przyszły projekt globalnego systemu handlu: Potężni członkowie mogą zawsze zagrozić rezygnacją z WTO jako forum dla tworząc reguły handlowe i skupiają się na (mega-) regionalnych, a nie na wielostronnych transakcjach handlowych, co osłabia centralizację WTO. W odpowiedzi na zmiany WTO, które tworzą większą równość wśród wszystkich państw członkowskich, potężni członkowie mogą po prostu ustanowić nowe, jeszcze bardziej nierówne instytucje, które osłabiają iw pewnym stopniu zastępują instytucję wielostronną. Proces ten można zilustrować w kontekście globalnego systemu handlu: powolne postępy w negocjacjach z Ad-Dauhy doprowadziły do debat na temat reformy systemu handlu, takich jak porzucenie konsensusu w podejmowaniu decyzji w sprawie głosowania większością głosów. Jednak takie reformy nie zostały wszczęte. Zamiast tego, zastój w WTO raczej generował innowacyjność instytucjonalną, aby uniknąć blokady poprzez coraz bardziej dwustronne i (mega-) regionalne, a nie wielostronne podejścia. Obecnie istnieje spaghetti miska (Bhagwati 1995) umów handlowych: Setki takich umów o wolnym handlu zostały zakończone. Jednak dwustronne i regionalne reguły handlu powodują coraz większą nierówność niż wielostronne reguły rządzące rynkiem, ponieważ mniej silne kraje mają mniej, jeśli istnieją jakieś opcje w celu zawetowania propozycji silniejszej i mniej możliwości tworzenia koalicji. Niedawno mega-regionalne negocjacje handlowe stały się coraz bardziej istotne. Jeśli mega-regionale takie jak TPP i TTIP mają siedzibę, wiele państw trzecich, w tym uprawnień wzrastających i krajów rozwijających się, prawdopodobnie będzie cierpieć z powodu negatywnego wpływu tych umów. Porozumienia handlowe prowadzą do zmian w handlu. Na przykład niższe koszty handlowe między USA a UE prowadziłyby do wzrostu wymiany handlowej między obydwoma gospodarkami a ograniczonym obrotem z krajami trzecimi. Ponadto w odniesieniu do TTIP USA i UE będą pisać nowe przepisy w dziedzinach takich jak prawa własności intelektualnej, które mogłyby zwiększyć próg dla przedsiębiorstw, które chcą wejść na rynek północnoamerykański i europejski. Oczekuje się, że TTIP negatywnie wpłynie na wiele krajów rozwijających się i gospodarek wschodzących, w tym Chiny (Felbermayr i in., 2018). Chiny i inne rozwijające się i wschodzące gospodarki, w tym Tajlandia, będą miały negatywny wpływ na TPP (Petri amp Plummer 2018). Dlaczego więc wszystkie strony trzecie są wykluczone z negocjacji mega-regionalnych, które chcą zaakceptować zinstytucjonalizowaną nierówność w kontekście rozwoju porozumień mega-regionalnych? Wiele osób nie ma wyboru. Prawdopodobnie będą musieli respektować reguły mega-regionów w przyszłości, mimo że nie mieli pojęcia o kształtowaniu ich. Nie mogą też powstrzymywać tych inicjatyw, które występują poza wielostronnym systemem handlowym. W kontekście TTIP i TPP państwa silne, prowadzone przez USA i UE, napędzają instytucjonalne przepisy, które przynoszą korzyści i generują pozytywne (Pauwelyn 2017) oraz negatywne efekty zewnętrzne, na przykład poprzez przekierowanie handlu. Wszystkie państwa, które nie znajdują się w tabeli negocjacji w sprawie nowych porozumień mega-regionalnych, będą w dalszym ciągu rządzącymi w odniesieniu do wielu ważnych reguł handlowych w przyszłości. Co więcej, lepsza zewnętrzna opcja dawnych uprawnień w kontekście mega-regionalsów podnosi nacisk na członkostwo w WTO. Na przykład w związku z rozprzestrzenianiem się umów dwustronnych i (mega-regionalnych) w ministerstwie WTO z 2018 r. Wiele państw członkowskich, w tym rosnące uprawnienia, uznało, że musiały zgodzić się z proponowanym pakietem z Nairobi. Brak jakiegokolwiek efektu mógłby przyczynić się do zakończenia organizacji opartej na konsensusie jako znaczącego forum negocjacyjnego, a wprowadzanie w ery zdominowałyby mega-regionalne transakcje, takie jak partnerstwo transatlantyckie, gdzie USA wybierają co in i (Guida 2018). Jak powiedział prezydent USA ds. Finansów Senatu: Ameryka nie może czekać na Chiny i Indie Zamiast tego, powinniśmy agresywnie dążyć do zawarcia wysokich standardowych transakcji handlowych z naszymi partnerami, którzy są gotowi przestrzegać zasad i spełnić warunki naszego porozumienia (Guida 2018). Zdaniem innych obserwatorów, kraje rozwijające się nie budziły śladów, że to jest inny świat Jeśli nie będą grały w WTO, USA i UE wezmą piłkę i zagrają gdzieś indziej (Guida 2018). TTIP i TPP mogłyby zatem zostać uznane za wezwanie do budzenia się dla innych członków WTO, którzy będą kompromitować, obawiając się, że USA i UE straci wszelkie zainteresowanie wielostronnym forum negocjacji WTO. To jest złe wieści dla krajów rozwijających się: szczególnie silniejsze, kraje biedniejsze potrzebują WTO, aby mieć większą szansę na wysłuchanie. Chiny i Mega-Regionalne Negocjacje Handlowe Wyłączenia krajów rozwijających się z negocjowania nowych porozumień, takich jak TPP i TTIP, których zasady, które będą musiały podążać ze względu na silną pozycję rynków zainteresowanych krajów, budzą ważne pytania dotyczące nierówności. Najbardziej obawiają się mega-regionów, które są stosunkowo mało znaczące ze względu na status ekonomiczny i pozycję geopolityczną. Na przykład kraje afrykańskie nie są częścią negocjacji mega-regionalnych. Z drugiej strony, rosnące uprawnienia są w lepszej pozycji, aby przystąpić do konkursu o regionalne partnerstwa handlowe ze względu na ich wagę ekonomiczną i polityczną. Rzeczywiście, Chiny kładły nacisk na to wyzwanie. Częściowo w reakcji na TTIP i TPP Chiny promowały Inicjatywę w sprawie pasa i dróg, która skupia się na łączności i współpracy między Chinami a resztą Eurazji. Aktywnie promuje także regionalne partnerstwa handlowe, popychając regionalne kompleksowe partnerstwo gospodarcze (RCEP), proponowaną umowę mega-handel w Azji. Niedawno Chiny zaczęły zainteresować przyłączeniem się do innych mega-regionów, przede wszystkim TPP. Jej postawa wskazuje, że Chiny mogą być skłonne przystąpić do TPP na późniejszym etapie (Naughton i in., 2018). Symulacje kilku trwających negocjacji mega-regionalnych sugerują, że przystąpienie Chin do TPP i członkostwo w RCEP przyniosłoby najwyższe wyniki dobrobytu dla Chin (Li i in., 2018). Chociaż Chiny stały się inicjatorem i aktywnym kibicem mega-regionalnych negocjacji handlowych i powiązanych działań (He Yang Yang 2018), Brazylia i Indie były bardziej pasywne. Indie martwi się, jak TTIP i TPP będą miały wpływ na gospodarkę. Jeśli chodzi o TPP, Indie są zaniepokojone tym, że znalazł się w grze w szachy między chińskim smokiem a orlem amerykańskim (Lehmann amp Fernandes 2017). W przeszłości Indie przestrzegły umów o wolnym handlu i koncentrowały się głównie na porozumieniach regionalnych i południowo-południowych (Lehmann amp Fernandes 2017). Podczas gdy Indie uczestniczą w negocjacjach RCEP, to kraj nie naciskał na inne inicjatywy regionalne i mega-regionalne. W porównaniu z Chinami Indie w ciągu ostatnich dziesięcioleci znosiły bariery w handlu międzynarodowym. Ostrożne podejście do liberalizacji handlu można wytłumaczyć skomplikowanym systemem politycznym Indiasu, który podważa kompromisy w polityce handlowej i obawy o potencjalne skutki dla biednych: Prawie jedna trzecia mieszkańców Indii nadal żyje poniżej granicy ubóstwa (Lehmann amp Fernandes 2017). Jednocześnie ryzyko izolacji i bycia zwykłym podmiotem zapewnia rządowi indyjskiemu powody, aby stać się bardziej aktywnymi na arenie handlowej przede wszystkim w systemie wielostronnym, ale także w grupie G20. Na przykład, być może z Chinami i Brazylią, Indie mogłyby zaproponować negocjacje mające na celu otwarcie rynków towarów i usług wśród wszystkich rozwiniętych gospodarek i gospodarek rozwijających się i rozwijających się G20, z możliwością uczestnictwa innych osób na późniejszym etapie (Kelkar amp Singh, 2018). Brazylia nie była zbyt zaangażowana w negocjowanie umów o wolnym handlu, a zamiast tego zdecydowanie koncentrowała się na wielostronnej ścieżce liberalizacji handlu w ramach WTO. Główną umową preferencyjną Brazils pod względem wartości handlowej jest MERCOSUR (Południowy Wspólny Rynek). Brazylia nie należy do żadnej z niedawnych lub obecnych negocjacji mega-regionalnych i nie zawarła żadnych znaczących umów o wolnym handlu w ostatnich dwóch dekadach (George 2018). Kraj musi podjąć decyzję, czy należy skoncentrować się na zwiększaniu konkurencyjności swojej branży lub wzmocnić swoją pozycję na arenie międzynarodowej zarządzania finansami (Giacomone 2018). Podczas gdy Brazylia niechętnie liberalizuje handel i utrzymuje relatywnie wysokie bariery handlowe, pojawiły się ostatnie oznaki potencjalnej zmiany postaw. Wraz z innymi kierowcami, takimi jak niedawne spowolnienie gospodarcze, TTIP zdawało się, że rząd brazylijski i jego elity ekonomiczne przekonały się, że jest bardziej otwarty na globalizowany świat (Malamud 2017). Ponadto pojawiły się liczne pomysły na nowe lub wznowione inicjatywy Ameryki Łacińskiej, na przykład zbliżenie MERCOSUR i Pacific Alliance oraz przyspieszenie rozszerzenia MERCOSUR częściowo w odpowiedzi na TTIP. Jako regiony największej gospodarki, Brazylia ma kluczowe znaczenie, aby wpływać na potencjał i granice tych opcji (Giacalone 2018). Można zatem powiedzieć, że mega-regionalne negocjacje handlowe mają wpływ na integrację regionalną Ameryki Łacińskiej i stanowisko Brazylii wobec umów handlowych. Podczas gdy rosnące uprawnienia mają pewną swobodę w walce z inicjatywami TPP i TTIP zdominowanymi przez USA i UE, wciąż są zaniepokojeni wykluczeniem tych umów. Chińscy rzecznicy kilkakrotnie wyrazili obawy o wykluczenie krajów z TTIP i TPP. Rozpoczęcie negocjacji w sprawie TPP wywołało niepokój w Chinach, jak TPP może uosabiać strategię USA dotyczącą Chin. Niedawno światło reflektorów zostało przeniesione do TTIP i wyzwań tej umowy transatlantyckiej dla Chin (Yang amp Yiwei 2018). W świetle TPP i TTIP chińscy eksperci i decydenci wciąż podkreślali wagę WTO dla globalnego systemu handlowego, a także potencjału G20. Społeczność międzynarodowa powinna utrzymywać komunikację na temat handlu światowego, zwłaszcza poprzez instytucjonalizację konferencji ministrów handlu z G20, jak podkreślił Wang Wen, dyrektor wykonawczy Instytutu Badań nad Finansami Chongyang, podczas rozmów na temat powstania porozumień handlowych (Yiming 2018 ). Komunikat liderów G20 Szczytu w Hangzhou podczas prezydencji chińskiej G20 podkreśla nacisk na współpracę w celu dalszego wzmocnienia WTO. Ogólną troską jest to, że rosnące potęgi, takie jak Chiny, mogłyby reagować na negocjacje mega-regionalne prowadzone przez USA i UE, wspierając przeciwstawne bloki handlowe. Zamiast podążać w dużej mierze ekskluzywnym podejściem, partnerzy transatlantyccy powinni skoncentrować się na globalnej współpracy i pracować z rosnącymi mocarstwami i krajami rozwijającymi się, szczególnie biorąc pod uwagę te państwa potencjał gospodarczy i globalne wyzwania w innych dziedzinach polityki, takie jak zmiany klimatyczne, które można pokonać wspólnie (Berger amp Brandi 2018). Wnioski Mega-regionalne umowy handlowe naruszają wielostronny system handlowy bardziej niż kiedykolwiek. Aby zapewnić przyszłość WTO jako forum negocjacji, konieczne jest przedyskutowanie reformy globalnego systemu handlowego. Taka debata stała się bardziej naciskowa z perspektywy krajów rozwijających się, które najbardziej cierpią z powodu osłabienia WTO. Ten artykuł ilustruje, że status quo statusu instytucjonalnego może ograniczyć wysiłki aktorów, aby wykorzystać ich zmienne stanowiska władzy. Pokazało to również, że chodzi tu nie tylko o status instytucji, co ma znaczenie, w tym przypadku WTO, ale również kontekst instytucjonalny i państwa członkowskie, które nie są dostępne. Jeśli, podobnie jak w przypadku WTO, opcje zewnętrzne są lepsze dla dominujących członków dawnych i wzrastających uprawnień niż dla podwładnych, wewnętrzne instytucje blokujące mogłyby doprowadzić do utworzenia nowych instytucji, które nie tylko mają tendencję do rozmnażania, ale mogą nawet pogłębiać nierówności . W tym artykule pokazano, jak ważne jest ocenianie nie tylko formalnych, ale i nieformalnych wymiarów nierówności instytucjonalnych. W WTO nierównomierny jest nierówny i znaczący, chociaż formalna równość jest silnie zinstytucjonalizowana w praktyce podejmowania decyzji opartych na konsensusie. W WTO ideały i czynniki materialne zdają się sprzyjać mniejszej nierówności w czasie: wymogi normatywne zazwyczaj promują równość, a nie nierówność. O ile w ostatnim czasie globalna siła gospodarcza uległa przesunięciu, a nowe mocarstwa, takie jak Chiny, Indie i Brazylia, zmniejszyły nierówność możliwości ekonomicznych, mogłoby to sprzyjać bardziej formalnej i nieformalnej równości. Jednocześnie w tym artykule pokazano, że nierówność instytucjonalna WTO stwarza dylemat. O ile nierówność w WTO zostanie spłaszczona ze względu na czynniki materialne lub ideologiczne, skuteczność instytucji może być postrzegana jako ograniczona, zmniejszając jej korzyści, głównie dla potężnych krajów, którzy następnie porzucają WTO i system wielostronny. Międzynarodowe organizacje, które odzwierciedlają, jak energia jest dystrybuowana w systemie międzynarodowym i działa jako pojazdy dla interesów państw najsilniejszych ekonomicznie, to tylko jedna z części opowieści. Druga część to potężne kraje, które angażują się na forum na zakupy, wspierając mega-regionalne negocjacje. Grupa G20 mogłaby odegrać kluczową rolę w przyszłości WTO oraz bardzo potrzebną reformę globalnego systemu handlu (Berger amp Brandi 2018). Taka reforma jest wyzwaniem, zwłaszcza jeśli ma to również przyczynić się do agendy ONZ 2030 w sprawie zrównoważonego rozwoju i SDG. Wyeliminowanie luki między realiami globalnego systemu handlowego a aspiracjami Agendy 2030 jest ogromnym wyzwaniem. Nie można skutecznie zaradzić w WTO ani ONZ. G20 jest odpowiednim forum pomagającym pokonać tę lukę. Referencje Alter, KJ amp Meunier, S 2009, Polityka złożoności reżimu międzynarodowego, perspektywy polityczne, t. 7, nie. 1, str. 13-24. Arrighi, G 2007, Adam Smith w Pekinie: Lineages XXI wieku, Nowy Jork: Verso. Babies, S 2017. Królestwo Middling: Hype i Rzeczywistość Chińczyków Rise Foreign Affairs, obj. 90, nie. 5, str. 79-88. Beeson, M amp Bell, S 2009, G-20 i Międzynarodowe zarządzanie gospodarką: Hegemonia, kolektywizm lub oba, Global Governance, t. 15, nie. 67, str. 67-86. Beeson, Mark. Miejsce handlu Chiny, Stany Zjednoczone i Ewolucja międzynarodowej gospodarki politycznej, przegląd międzynarodowej gospodarki politycznej, obj. 16, nie. 4, str. 729-41. Berger, A Brandi C 2018, G20 i przyszłość globalnego systemu handlowego, Bonn: Niemiecki Instytut Rozwoju Deutsches Institut fr Entwicklungspolitik. Berger, A amp Brandi, C 2018, Co powinni robić aktorzy z dziedziny polityki rozwoju? O transatlantyckich partnerstwach handlowych i inwestycyjnych (TTIP) Bonn: Niemiecki Instytut Rozwoju Deutsches Institut fr Entwicklungspolitik. Bhagwati, Jagdish. 1995. Liberalizacja handlu i uczciwe wymogi handlowe: Rozwiązanie problemów związanych z normami środowiskowymi i normami pracy World Economy, vol. 18, nie. 6, str. 745759. Breslin, S 2017, Chinas Globalna rola wschodząca: niezadowolona odpowiedzialna moc, polityka, t. 30, str. 52-62. Drezner, DW 2009, moc i zagrożenie złożoności reżimu międzynarodowego, perspektywy polityki, t. 7, nr 1, str. 65-70. Evans, P 2008, jest alternatywną globalizacją możliwą polityką społeczną, t. 36, nie. 2, str. 271-305. Fehl, C 2017, nierówna moc i instytucjonalne podejście do zarządzania światem: sprawa kontroli zbrojeń, przegląd badań międzynarodowych, t. 30, nie. 3, str. 505-531. Felbermayr, G, Kohler, W, Aichele, R, Klee, G, Yalcin, E, 2018, Potencjalne skutki transatlantyckiego partnerstwa na rzecz handlu i inwestycji (TTIP) w sprawie rozwijających się i wschodzących gospodarek, Ifo Institut, Mnchen. Gilpin, R 1987, The Political Economy of International Relations, Princeton: Princeton University Press. Guida, V 2018, Nairobi is make-or-break moment for WTO, Politico, 12 December. Available from: politico. eu. 31 August 2018. Hung, HF 2009, China and the Transformation of Global Capitalism, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. Hurrell, A 2006, Hegemony, Liberalism and World Order: What Space for Would-be Great Powers, International Affairs, vol. 82, no.1, pp.1-19. Ikenberry, John. 2008, The Rise of China and the Future of the West: Can the Liberal System Survive, Foreign Affairs, JanuaryFebruary, pp. 23-37. Margulis, ME. amp Porter, T 2017, Governing the Global Land Grab: Multipolarity, Ideas, and Complexity in Transnational Governance, Globalizations, vol. 10, no. 1, pp. 65-86. Mittelman, JH 2017, Global Bricolage: Emerging Market Powers and Polycentric Governance, Third World Quarterly, vol. 34, no. 1, pp. 23-37. Naughton, B, Kroeber, AR, De Jonquires, G amp Webster, G 2018, What Will the TPP Mean for China, Foreign Policy, October. Negri, A amp Hardt, M 2000, Empire. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Pieterse, JN 2000, After Post-Development, Third World Quarterly, vol. 21, no. 2, pp. 175-191. Ruggie, JG, 1996, Constructing the World Polity: Essays on International Institutionalization, London: Routledge. Stephen, MD, 2017, Rising Regional Powers and International Institutions: The Foreign Policy Orientations of India, Brazil and South Africa, Global Society, vol. 26, no. 3, pp. 289-309. Strange, Gerard. 2017, Chinas Post-Listian Rise: Beyond Radical Globalisation Theory and the Political Economy of Neoliberal Hegemony, New Political Economy, vol. 16, pp. 539-559. Subramanian, A. 2017, The Inevitable Superpower: Why Chinas Dominance Is a Sure Thing, Foreign Affairs, vol. 90, no. 5, pp. 66-78. Wang, H, amp French, E, 2017, China in global economic governance, Asian Economic Policy Review, vol. 9, no. 2, pp. 254-271. Yang, J amp Yiwei, W 2018, TTIP: The Economic and Strategic Effects. CIIS. Available from: ciis. org. cn. 31 August 2018. Yiming, G 2018, Chinas Exclusion from TPP and TTIP against Globalization. Available from: china. org. cn. 31 August 2018. Young, AR 2017, Perspectives on the Changing Global Distribution of Power: Concepts and Context, Politics, vol. 30, no. 1, pp. 2-14. About the Author: Dr Clara Brandi is a Senior Researcher and Project Leader in the Department World Economy and Development Financing at the German Development Institute Deutsches Institut fr Entwicklungspolitik (DIE). Clara Brandi studied economics at the University of Wisconsin, Madison, and at the Albert-Ludwigs-Universitt, Freiburg. As Michael-Wills-Scholar, she completed the MPhil in Politics at the University of Oxford. She received her PhD from the European University Institute, Florence. Her main research interests include global governance, international trade policy and trade agreements and interlinkages between trade, development and climate change. Read More Read Less Latest ArticlesFuture of the Multilateral Trading System: Why the WTO Remains Indispensable World Trade Organization (WTO) Date Written: March 30, 2018 From 1947 the Multilateral Trading System (MTS), based on the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), was the engine for stability, unprecedented economic growth, welfare and prosperity in the post-war global order. These objectives were sustained with the coming into force of the World Trade Organization (WTO), in 1995, as the successor to the GATT. The WTO inherited the GATT acquis, the credits from the remarkable accomplishments of the GATT, but also its challenges and, in a radically altered global environment, defined by the 1991 collapse of the Soviet Union, the disintegration of the former Yugoslavia, significant shifts in the relative balance of power and the emergence of multi-polarity. In its Twentieth Anniversary, the WTO has registered strong gains. Its regular work is functioning at high levels of technical and operational efficiency in the administration of its Agreement. Its Dispute Settlement function is highly regarded in public international law. Historically, the Organization is expanding its membership, through multilateral accession negotiations in regular work, that is integrating diverse economies, previously outside the system, into the rules-based MTS, based on a balance of rights and obligations and on the foundation of the core values of the market economy, the rule of law and good governance. In its Twentieth Anniversary, the role of the WTO is indispensable and its functions are non-substitutable. It continues to uniquely deliver the global public good of non-discriminatory trade rules. However, the WTO has been unable to conclude the Doha Round of Negotiations launched in 2001. This failure is seen as hobbling its systemic legislative function and framing the wider negative perceptions of the Organization. It is confronted by this failure, and other inherited and recent challenges that are weighing it down. Several of these challenges have become more acute due to changes in the international trading environment and domestic political economies. Multilateral trade rules require system-wide regular updates to take account of these rapid transformations in the global and domestic environments to ensure that the organization is in lock step with commercial and public policy realities. Protectionism is more pernicious than ever, fuelled by the increased frequency of financial and economic crises. Public policy concerns have to be reconciled with trade liberalization. PTAs are proliferating, due in part to sluggish multilateral rule-making. Geopolitics is resurgent with risks for rule-making and growth. Although the role of the WTO remains indispensable, the original mandates of multilateral institutions do not establish them permanently. At particular generational turns, defined by crises and challenges, multilateral institutions must re-define (or reaffirm) and re-position themselves to ensure contemporaneity, retention of pole position in their area of competent jurisdiction and, effectiveness. Responding to these challenges requires the courage of strategic leadership with three critical components: deep knowledge of the past and its lessons a prospectus for change and, a capacity to effect such change. Keywords: General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), World Trade Organization (WTO), Multilateral Trading System (MTS), trade negotiations, WTO accession negotiation, global economic governance, international cooperation and global order Suggested Citation: Suggested Citation Osakwe, Chiedu, Future of the Multilateral Trading System: Why the WTO Remains Indispensable (March 30, 2018). Asian Journal of WTO International Health Law and Policy, Vol. 10:1. Available at SSRN: ssrnabstract2599404Multilateral, Regional and Bilateral Energy Trade Governance Queen Mary, University of London Date Written: December 26, 2017 The current international energy trade governance system is fragmented and multi-layered. Streamlining it for greater legal cohesiveness and international political and economic cooperation would promote global energy security. The current article explores three levels of energy trade governance: multilateral, regional and bilateral. Most energy-rich countries are part of the multilateral trading system, which is institutionalized by the World Trade Organization (WTO). The article analyzes the multilateral energy trade governance system by focusing on the WTO and energy transportation issues. Regionally, the article focuses on five major regional agreements and their energy-related aspects and examines the various causes that explain the proliferation of regional trade agreements, their compatibility with WTO law, and then provides several examples of regional energy trade governance throughout the world. When it comes to bilateral energy trade governance, this article only addresses the European Unions (EU) bilateral energy trade relations. The article explores ways in which gaps could be filled and overlaps eliminated whilst remaining true to the high-level normative framework, concentrating on those measures that would enhance EU energy security. Keywords: Multilateral energy trade governance regional energy trade governance Energy Charter Treaty MERCOSUR ASEAN EU energy trade governance WTO IRENA raw materials natural resources shale gas. Suggested Citation: Suggested Citation Leal-Arcas, Rafael and Grasso, Costantino and Alemany Rios, Juan, Multilateral, Regional and Bilateral Energy Trade Governance (December 26, 2017). Renewable Energy Law and Policy Review, Vol. 6(1), pp. 38-87, 2018 Queen Mary School of Law Legal Studies Research Paper No. 1882017. Available at SSRN: ssrnabstract2542897 Queen Mary University of London - School of Law ( email ) 67-69 Lincolns Inn Fields London, WC2A 3JB United KingdomThe Challenges Facing the Multilateral Trading System in Addressing Global Public Policy Objectives Despite a record-breaking 14.5 per cent increase in world merchandise exports, the effects of the financial crisis and global recession are still hampering faster economic recovery. Relatively high oil prices combined with persistent unemployment and measures designed to reduce budget deficits have undermined short-term growth prospects. While SouthSouth trade continues to explode, trade imbalances i. e. the gap between exports and imports widened in 2017 compared to 2009 (though smaller than pre-crisis levels). Meanwhile, trade negotiations under the Doha Round have reached an impasse, generating uncertainties about the future of the World Trade Organization (WTO) as a negotiating forum. Under these circumstances, should the system rethink its decision-making process founded upon the predominance of member states, the principle of consensus and the notion of single undertaking, as some critics have suggested And, if so, how could such a reform agenda be initiated at the WTO Moreover, beyond the negotiating function of the WTO, the paralysis of the system also raises urgent questions about the ability of the system to respond to pressing challenges of our times, such as trade and climate change, or food security and price volatility. Index terms Thematic keywords160: What we are seeing today is the paralysis in the negotiating function of the WTO, whether it is on market access or on the rule-making. What we are facing is the inability of the WTO to adapt and adjust to emerging global trade priorities, those you cannot solve through bilateral deals. Pascal Lamy, at an informal heads of delegation meeting of the Trade Negotiating Committee, 26 July 2017 1 The 200809 financial crisis and the current sovereign debt crisis in Europe have not only highlighted the high level of economic interdependencies existing worldwide, but also the growing challenges in pursuing international collaborative actions to address urgent sustainable development challenges. In a rapidly changing multi-polar world in which economic wealth is progressively shifting towards the East and the South, and in which resource constraints have become increasingly pressing, international cooperation remains in crisis. The rise of emerging countries like China, India or Brazil and the relative decline of traditional economic powers have created new opportunities, as reflected by the unprecedented growth in SouthSouth trade observed over the last decade or so. However, it has also generated new tensions, not least between countries with large trade surpluses and those with growing trade deficits. Such tensions are equally palatable in international negotiations such as the ones dealing with climate change. 2 Meanwhile, the number of hungry people is estimated to have reached one billion in 2009, catapulting food security back to the top of the political agenda. As growth in demand continues to rise faster than increases in supply due fundamentally to low productivity growth food prices are expected to remain high and volatile in the coming years. Several factors have contributed to enhancing price volatility: low stocks resulting from a succession of weather-related production shortfall, growing demand for biofuelsfeedstock, rising energy prices and a depreciation of the US dollar however, these have been aggravated by policy responses such as export restrictions. 3 This rapidly changing environment and the pressing needs for international cooperative action to address concerns around food security, climate change or unsustainable trade imbalances contrast sharply with the current paralysis of the multilateral trading system. The Doha Round of trade negotiations under the World Trade Organization (WTO) has now remained in a limbo for several months with no real perspectives for the near future. While several factors explain the stalemate in the ten-year-old trade talks, this paralysis raises uncertainties about the future of the multilateral trading system. 4 As a contribution to this discussion, this chapter looks at how the multilateral trading system has sought to address global public policy objectives, and how it can do so in the future. After a short review of current trends in international trade and recent developments which have led to the current crisis in the Doha Round, Section 3 considers possible options for reforming the way in which the WTO conducts negotiations. Finally, Section 4 focuses on how the WTO has sought to respond to specific public policy objectives in the past using the case of food security as an example and what this tells us about the way in which the multilateral trading system relates tobroader global public policy goals. 5 Following a sharp 12 per cent drop in 2009, the volume of world merchandise exports increased by a record-breaking 14.5 per cent in 2017, allowing global trade to recover to pre-crisis levels. This figure, the largest since data collection began in 1950, accompanied a 3.6 per cent increase in global gross domestic product (GDP). According to the WTO (WTO, 2017a), world trade growth should settle to a more modest 5.8 per cent in 2017, with a 2.5 per cent increase in global GDP (see Figure 9.1). Unsurprisingly, Asia exhibited the fastest real export growth 23.1 per cent with Chinese and Japanese exports increasing by 28.4 and 27.5 per cent, respectively. Meanwhile, merchandise trade grew by 10.8 per cent in Europe, and 15.4 per cent in the US. Overall developing countries and economies in transition accounted for 45 per cent of total world exports, the highest share ever (WTO, 2017a). 6 Rising commodity prices and a depreciating US currency meant that trade growth in dollar terms at 22 per cent exceeded the increase in volume terms. In particular, regions that rely on natural resource exports such as Africa, the Middle East or South America experienced lower growth in trade volumes but significant increases in the dollar value of their exports. African exports were up by 6.5 per cent in volume terms, but by 28 per cent in dollar terms. Similarly, Latin American exports grew by just 6.2 per cent in volume terms but by 25 per cent in dollar terms (WTO, 2017b). Figure 9.1 World merchandise exports and GDP, 200811 (in percentage change) Percentage change compared with same month of the previous year. Source: WTO (2017b). 7 Meanwhile, according to the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD), total foreign direct investments (FDI) increased from US1.185 to 1.244 trillion in 2017, largely due to increased flow to developing countries which, together with transition economies, accounted for more than half of total FDI (UNCTAD, 2017). Outward FDI from emerging economies also reached record highs, with most of their investment directed towards other countries in the South. 8 While these figures look impressive, the 2017 increase in merchandise trade did not suffice to return exports to levels consistent with 19902008 trends. On the investment front, despite a 5 per cent increase compared to 2009, global FDI flows have remained lower than their pre-crisis average (200507), and 37 per cent below their 2007 peak (UNCTAD, 2017). And while emerging economies in Latin America and South-East Asia experienced a rapid growth, FDI flows continued to contract in developed countries, Africa and South Asia. 9 More generally, as world output in 2009 was depressed, the WTO argues that higher growth in 2017 was to be expected, particularly as GDP growth often reached 4 per cent or more in recent years (WTO, 2017a). Several factors might explain why trade and output grew more slowly than they might have. In 2017, relatively high oil prices raised energy costs for households and business. High unemployment rates also affected domestic consumption and import demand in developed countries. Finally, attempts in Europe, the US and elsewhere to reduce budget deficits led to cuts in spending and revenue, undermining short-term growth prospects. The negative impacts of the financial crisis and global recession are therefore likely to remain for some time despite the record rebound of trade in 2017. 10 In the US, a low national savings rate and high private consumption as a share of GDP have continued to sustain demand for imported consumer goods, fuelling rapid export-led growth in emerging economies. Over the last 10 to 15 years, these developments have resulted in large imbalances, with sizeable current account deficits accumulating in the US in particular, and large current account surpluses in others, notably China, Germany and Japan. These have in turn generated political tensions, evident in the USChina controversy over exchange rate policies. In 2017, trade imbalances remained smaller than pre-crisis levels, but for most countries, except China, the gap between exports and imports widened compared to 2009 (see Figures 9.3 and 9.4). As Figure 9.2 shows, the US trade deficit increased from roughly US550 billion to US690 billion but remained lower than the US880 billion seen in 2008. Meanwhile, Chinas trade surplus fell from nearly US300 billion in 2008 to just over US180 billion in 2017. In 2017, the trade deficit of the European Union (EU) widened beyond 2009 levels, despite Germanys US200 billion trade surplus, even though the overall EU deficit was smaller than in 2008. Japan was an exception to the overall trend towards smaller imbalances, as its trade surplus nearly quadrupled in 2017 compared to pre-crisis levels. 11 There is widespread consensus that current imbalances are not sustainable in the long term. Persistently high levels of debt-financed household consumption in the US will have to return to slightly lower historical levels (Mayer, 2017). At the same time, low consumption rates and high national savings in China have prompted calls for Beijing to develop its internal market and gradually move from investment and export to consumer-led growth. These trends are likely to affect both the size and composition of global demand in years ahead. This is partly because increased Chinese consumption might not fully compensate a possible decrease in US demand growth, but also because the two economies tend to import different baskets of goods, with China buying more raw material, commodities and food, for example. Unless other trade surplus countries such as Germany or Japan also enhance their domestic consumption, changes in global demand will have major negative repercussions on developing country exports, and also on employment particularly in manufacturing sectors such as textiles and clothing (Mayer, 2017). Figure 9.2 Trade imbalances in selected economies, 200810 (in US million) Source: WTO (2017b). 12 SouthSouth trade has also continued to expand, and now represents roughly 50 per cent of developing country exports. Africas trade volumes with its emerging partners have doubled in nominal value over the decade and now amount to 37 per cent of the continents total trade (AFDB et al. 2017). While China represents Africas leading emerging partner, having surpassed the US in volume terms, the sum of the continents trade with its other emerging partners (such as Turkey, Brazil, Korea and India) is now even larger than its trade with China. While these developments provide new opportunities export markets, technology transfer, aid and other forms of cooperation African exports to other developing countries largely remain concentrated on primary products, with little evidence to date that SouthSouth trade has prompted real structural transformation. Figure 9.3 Importsexports: US and China, 200511 (in US million) 13 Figure 9.4 Importsexports: Germany and the EU, 200511 (in US million) Source: WTO (2017b). 14 Since January 2017, the Doha Round has continued to flounder, with deadlines for concluding the ten-year talks being missed at the end of that year and the next, and now having no end in sight. Over the course of the year, the US repeatedly called for mandatory participation in sectoral agreements for manufactured products, due to slash tariffs across an entire industry. Brazil, China and India rejected US demands for major emerging economies to take on particular responsibilities, and disputed Washingtons claim that the December 2008 draft texts disproportionately penalise the US calling instead on the US to clarify what specific concessions Washington might offer in return for increased market access. 15 Meanwhile, the G-33 group of developing countries made a series of proposals in favour of a strong special safeguard mechanism that they could use to defend domestic agricultural producers from sudden import surges or price depressions. The US and other exporting countries continued to insist that developing country flexibilities should not undermine growth in normal trade. 16 After a much-touted but ultimately fruitless stocktaking exercise in March 2017, members met for most of the remaining year in various informal bilateral and plurilateral groups described as variable geometry by WTO Director-General Pascal Lamy. Trade also featured in discussions on the sidelines of gatherings of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) and the Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation (APEC), and on the agenda of the Toronto and Seoul summits of the G-20 group of leading economies only for officials to find that the interests of major trading powers were still not close enough for a Doha deal to be struck in the near future. In early 2017, Mexico and Brazil tabled separate proposals on breaking the Doha deadlock, including possible trade-offs between separate negotiating areas such as agriculture and manufactured goods: however, these found little support at the global trade body. Recognising that gaps were increasingly hard to bridge, trade negotiators began discussing options for a soft landing. The release of revised texts or working documents in April 2017 confirmed fears that progress had stymied, with some negotiating group chairs only able to release state of play reports instead of new drafts. 17 Members then began quiet discussions on what a Plan B might look like. The plan was officially announced in May: members would finalise a mini-package focused on concerns of least developed countries (LDCs) for the December Ministerial, and also establish a work plan to resolve other outstanding issues. At the insistence of the US, the package was broadened to include non-LDC issues too. However, the package quickly began to unravel as members became unable to agree on which LDC and non-LDC items to include. Consensus proved elusive on the four main issues that LDCs sought to include: duty-free quota-free access for their exports an LDC services waiver, a step forward on cotton, and improved rules of origin. Similarly, trading powers were unable to agree on the growing number of non-LDC issues proposed, which ranged from fishery subsidies to trade facilitation and export competition. 18 By August, the plan for the December 2017 Ministerial had shifted away from producing an LDC-plus package: members instead decided they would focus on non-Doha issues and on a post-December work plan for concluding Doha, while holding parallel discussions on possible LDC deliverables. 19 Several factors explain members inability to conclude the trade talks. Some point to the fact that the negotiating process has become too politicised and complex, given the growing diversity and varied expectations of the WTOs 153-country membership. Others blame the rise of emerging economies such as Brazil, China and India, together with more assertive developing country coalitions. Others still link it to the global financial crisis and recent domestic difficulties in the EU and the US which have prevented those countries from fully exercising a leadership role in WTO negotiations. Finally, countries positions and negotiating interests have changed over time reflecting nowadays geopolitical dynamics. All these factors are relevant, but critics are increasingly pointing to a more fundamental flaw in the system, which relates to the way in which negotiations are conducted. Some observers have therefore argued that thorough reform of the system is needed to overcome the current paralysis. 20 Others remark that it is not necessarily the WTOs institutional procedures that have paralysed the organisation, but rather the way in which members have chosen to use its rules and practices (Rodriguez Mendoza and Wilke, 2017 Rolland, 2017). In fact some experts argue that the WTO has served as a model governance system at the international level, predominantly because of its automatic and enforceable dispute settlement system. Moreover, through its set of rules and disciplines, it is argued, the WTO has also been successful in preventing protectionist tendencies during economic crisis. 1 The Warwick Report . for example, provides one of the most notable and comprehensive stock-taking e (. ) 21 Nonetheless debate over institutional reform whether it is needed, in what form and via what kind of process has continued ever since the WTO was first established (Deere-Birbeck and Monagle, 2009). In 2003, after the failure of the Cancn Ministerial Conference, Pascal Lamy then EU trade commissioner qualified the WTO as medieval and called for its decision-making process to be revamped (Lamy, 2003). In recent years, various actors have proposed reforming virtually every aspect of the WTOs functioning from management and administration through the conduct of trade negotiations and dispute settlement, to capacity-building and cooperation with other institutions or the public at large (Deere-Birbeck and Monagle, 2009). The objectives behind those proposals and the pace of proposed reforms have been equally diverse, going from incremental improvements to radical changes in the way the institution functions. While some proposals have been introduced by governments, others have been put forward by academia, research institutes, civil society and other international organisations.1 The multilateral system itself has not been static in the face of these demands. Reforms or incremental changes have happened on a number of fronts, including at the management level, in external transparency, public participation in dispute settlement proceedings or in the way in which negotiations are conducted (Deere-Birbeck and Monagle, 2009). There are, however, diverging views on the desirability and impact of these changes and on whether they go far enough. 2 When governments launched the Uruguay Round of trade negotiations under the GATT in 1986, the decl (. ) 22 The debate sparked renewed interest as members prepared for the November 2009 Ministerial. After ten years of complex negotiations, characterised by missed deadlines and few substantive dividends, critics have argued that the bodys established rules, principles and practices of decision-making, carried over from the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT),2 are simply ill-suited to the fast changing challenges of our times. Some even argue that the GATTWTOs golden triangle of decision-making the dominance of contracting parties, the consensus principle and the logic of the single undertaking is unable to meet the challenges of modern global trade governance (Cottier and Elsig, 2009). 23 Strengthening the WTOs negotiation functioning will require balancing three competing demands: greater efficiency in the conduct of negotiations enhanced legitimacy including by better addressing public policy concerns and greater inclusiveness, so as to overcome power asymmetries and foster mutually beneficial outcomes. The following sections review some of the criticism and the proposed reform options for the WTOs conduct of negotiations in light of these objectives. 3 The consensus principle dates back to the International Trade Organization (ITO) and with it the e (. ) 4 With the exception of the improvements and clarifications of the DSU, the conduct, conclusion and (. ) 24 WTO negotiations are guided by the consensus principle and by the idea that they represent a single undertaking . Consensus is not interpreted as requiring unanimity however,3 if no present member state objects, consensus is assumed. The single undertaking, on the other hand, requires that all areas are negotiated and adopted by all parties at the same time .4 Both principles derive directly from the WTOs nature as a member-driven organisation. With the secretariat assuming an almost marginal role and the consensus principle on the basis of sovereign equality permeating all areas and functions of the organisation, the dominance of contracting parties is its main characteristic. 25 Each concept can be seen as a double-edged sword. The consensus principle is important for developing countries as, in theory, it guarantees that every member can veto any decisions, irrespective of its political or economic power. The single undertaking, on the other hand, has supported developing countries on numerous occasions, for instance when a group of Latin American members halted the establishment of the WTO until certain concessions of vital interest to developing countries had been made (Croome, 1995). 26 Both pillars nonetheless need to be seen in the context of the overarching power asymmetries at the WTO. In practice, wealthier nations can hold trade talks hostage more easily than poorer ones, because of the fact that they are better able to withstand political pressure to join a consensus even against great opposition (Steinberg, 2002 Cottier and Elsig, 2009 Low, 2009). The consensus principle is thus less about the actual consensual adoption of a final decision than about the process of consensus-building (Ismail and Vickers, 2017). The largest trading nations therefore bear particular responsibility for helping countries to reach agreement by guiding the process of consensus-building and facilitating an atmosphere of compromise. Ismail and Vickers thus note that, in the Doha round, developed countries also share considerable blame even responsibility for frustrating the process of consensus-building. It is disturbing that critics of the consensus principle raise efficiency concerns only when smaller developing countries and larger emerging economies (e. g. Brazil, China, India and South Africa) do not join the consensus of the developed countries (Ismail and Vickers, 2017). 27 This is similarly true for the single undertaking and the use of linkages to condition concessions in one area to progress in others. While in principle these could foster compromises by focusing negotiators attention on the greatest gains, in practice members tend to overemphasise the losses (Van Grasstek and Sauv, 2006). This is particularly true for the current round, where negotiators do not seek to establish linkages systematically with a view to achieving long-term benefits, but focus instead on achieving short-term gains for tactical reasons (Rodriguez Mendoza and Wilke, 2017). The introduction of linkages prevents certain areas from moving ahead independent of progress in others. As a result, even small deals cannot be reached, as new proposals prompt further linkages. 28 Proposals to reform those two core negotiating principles (Deere-Birbeck and Monagle, 2009) can be summarised in two categories: those introducing different voting systems, and those relating to variable geometry agreements including so-called plurilateral and critical mass agreements. 5 Note that weighted voting at the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund (IMF) is based on (. ) 29 Proposals on weighted voting (one suggestion for reforming the consensus principle) and critical mass agreements share a common idea. Power be it for voting, agenda setting or participation in negotiations would reflect a countrys economic significance. The allocation of votes could thus reflect a countrys share in global trade, GDP or the level of market openness. Some experts also suggest taking into account country size or population, arguing that this would ensure power is shared fairly among developed, emerging and other developing countries (Cottier and Takenoshita, 2008 Elsig, 2009). However, experience with weighted voting approaches in the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and World Bank show that the approach can easily manifest real power asymmetries rather than overcoming imbalances (Warwick Commission, 2007).5 30 The current voting system does not suffer from a large group of small countries blocking negotiations, but instead from a handful of powerful countries that are unable to reach agreement among themselves. The alternative, a simple majority vote, could be difficult to introduce as it would undermine the currently powerful position of developed countries by enabling groups of smaller countries to overrule them. Experience in the United Nations (UN) General Assembly indicates that many countries would systematically oppose the introduction of a simple majority vote (Anghie, 2005). 31 The concept of variable geometry agreements is an alternative to the single undertaking. Plurilateral agreements, for example, have already been used in the past. Here, the participation of all WTO members is not required in order to strike a deal and interested members are free to join the negotiation or not. Several experts have suggested reviving and enhancing this approach (Consultative Board, 2004 Elsig, 2008). The critical mass approach is slightly different in the sense that it requires that participating members represent at least a critical mass or a certain threshold of a sector under negotiation based on their collective level of economic activity, production, consumption or exports (Jackson, 2001). Supporters argue that the inclusion of import share in the threshold would ensure that critical mass agreements could not be misused by exporters to harmonise their export systems to the detriment of importers an issue they consider to be of increasing importance as, for instance, high-technology producing countries face shortages in needed raw materials that are extracted in only a handful of countries (ICTSD, 2017d). Proposed thresholds range from 75 to 90 per cent. Proponents argue that the threshold could further be coupled with the requirement to include at least a minimum number of countries. If constructed in a sensitive way, supporters suggest, this second requirement could ensure the legitimacy of a particular critical mass rather than only its efficiency. The Warwick Commission, for instance, notes that a positive global welfare benefit, to protect the principle of non-discrimination, and to accommodate explicitly the income distribution effects of rule-making would need to be part of a critical mass consideration, in particular when it relates to the formation of an agenda (Warwick Commission, 2007, 3). 32 It needs to be cautioned, however, that most of the proposals for a critical mass approach focus on negotiations on downstream modalities and concessions (basically market access), thus limiting thresholds to purely economic considerations. As the WTO moves towards addressing a greater array of trade-related policies, such a critical mass concept might be inappropriate. Small countries, for instance, may not have a particular export or import trade share in a certain sector and are thus not indispensable for a critical mass, yet they would be critically affected by any new rules be this on agriculture commodities or new regulation on services trade. This is particularly true as trends in rule-making increasingly serve as a reference for legal interpretation and new regulatory approaches are used as a reference and argument in non-related yet similar negotiations. Each negotiation is thus also about shaping global policy and law trends. 6 The agreements and associated legal instruments included in Annex 4 (hereinafter referred to as (. ) 33 Another aspect that continues to be disputed among the supporters of a critical mass approach is the most favoured nation (MFN) character of the final agreements. Current plurilateral WTO agreements (where no critical mass was required) only apply among the members that have signed them.6 If further strengthened, this approach has the potential to turn the WTO into an umbrella organisation facilitating group arrangements while losing its multilateral and thus participatory and inclusive character. To meet this concern, alternative proposals suggest extending the rights and benefits deriving from critical mass agreements on an MFN basis to all WTO members (Warwick Commission, 2007). This could preserve the multilateral character of the WTO and thus its integrity while supporting fast-track negotiations. 34 However, even the latter construct raises certain questions. First, assumin g that a given sector was irrelevant for a particular country at the time when a critical mass negotiation was concluded, it remains unclear how the country could be induced to join the agreement if the benefits already apply on an MFN basis. Also, it is unclear whether a country would be required to join the existing agreement or whether there would be an option to renegotiate the terms (Harbinson, 2009). If no changes were allowed, powerful groups could now conclude agreements that become relevant for developing countries only at a later stage, thus indirectly imposing their terms and conditions. Criticisms regarding a trend towards WTO-plus commitments in FTAs and the fear over the Anti-Counterfeit Trade Agreement (ACTA) introducing a new global benchmark for the protection of intellectual property come to mind in this respect (ICTSD, 2008b). 35 While some of the proposals discussed above might be promising, neither a review of the voting procedures nor a critical mass approach in isolation of other reforms seem to have the potential to fully achieve the three objectives of WTO reform, namely, efficiency, legitimacy and inclusiveness. Instead, if implemented in their simplest form, both concepts risk excluding smaller countries and exacerbating power asymmetries. Also, none of the proposed reforms would be likely to resolve the current deadlock in the Doha round which results, to a large extent, from political differences rather than weak procedural rules. In this respect, some critics have challenged the member-driven nature of the institution. They argue that a stronger WTO secretariat could be useful, particularly in times where members fail to initiate needed deliberations or where discussions are paralysed by individual member states political actions. If members are not prepared to defend and promote the principles they subscribed to, then the Secretariat must be free to do so, the Sutherland report noted already in 2004 (Consultative Board, 2004). 7 See for instance the 2003 Memorandum on the Need to Improve Internal Transparency and Participati (. ) 36 Such proposals, however, need to be seen in the light of already existing criticism over a too powerful and partial WTO secretariat. The same stakeholders fear that strengthening the secretariat could create a strong institution following its own internal agenda.7 Consequentially, the challenge would be a strong, yet neutral secretariat. Proponents agree that this could only be guaranteed if member states were to ensure a constant participation and oversight. Efforts on strengthening the secretariat would thus focus primarily on increased political support by member states rather than a budgetary increase or a mandate extension as advocated by others. The idea behind this is to redirect but not replace the preponderant role of member states, i. e. to strengthen the WTO through increased policy deliberation among its members. 8 For instance, during the 7th Ministerial Conference in 2009, the delegation of Uruguay called upon (. ) 37 One important starting point could be the election process of the Director General (Consultative Board, 2004 Steger, 2009). This process provides a critical opportunity to reflect on the most pressing challenges facing the organisation. If candidates were to take a strong position while countries provided them with clear indications on what is expected over the coming term, directors would receive a strong mandate to lead and guide even in critical times (Deere-Birbeck and Monagle, 2009, 74). The current practice of nodding through rather than electing a new Director General, without any internal and external reflection process, on the other hand, weakens the position of the Director General, the member states and the WTO as an institution (Keohane and Nye, 2000). A second point of entry could be the regular Ministerial Conferences. If members used the meetings to reflect on the standing of the WTO, the way forward and the actions expected in the coming years, the secretariat could guide the organisation accordingly over the coming months. In fact Ministerial Conferences were originally meant to provide for such a forum. Only with the launch of the Doha Round they have turned into pure negotiation gatherings. Numerous developing countries have consistently criticised this development.8 38 As described above, there has been no shortage of thoughtful ideas and recommendations from a variety of different sources and study groups. But some critics argue that these ideas have gone nowhere because they have had no process to feed into. Currently only one set of proposals is being discussed in a formalised manner at the WTO, namely those related to dispute settlement (WTO, 1999b). As foreseen by the original WTO agreements a special session of the Dispute Settlement Body (DSB) has been reviewing related reform proposals since 1997. Formally it proceeds outside of the Doha Round and is not part of the single undertaking. In practice, however, the review is used as a trade-off opportunity in the Doha Round which has prevented any conclusion over the last 14 years. To allow for a proper debate, other reform proposals will also need to be addressed in a formalised process at the WTO. Such a process would probably need to involve and engage trade ministers themselves to generate sufficient credibility and political traction. Ideally, the process should be co-chaired and co-owned by a developing and a developed country trade minister. 39 At the same time, the experience of the Dispute Settlement Understanding (DSU) review shows that any reform discussion must be de-linked from trade negotiations. Enforcing such an objective and non-concession-based discussion could be easier if various reform proposals were debated in a joint forum with a common objective and a single plan of action. Moreover, a joint process would facilitate the coordination of different reforms ensuring that the executive, legislative and judicial branches of the WTO do not develop in opposite directions but are mutually supportive. 40 A first opportunity to initiate such a process was missed at the 7th Ministerial Conference, in December 2009, essentially due to a lack of political will to push this agenda through. During the preparatory process and under the leadership of India, 18 developed and developing countries had proposed to address the need for an institutional reform in a formalised and long-term manner. The coalition, backed by almost the entire WTO membership, called upon the WTO to periodically engage in a process of review of its functioning, efficiency and transparency and upon the member states to consider systemic improvements, as appropriate. to establish an appropriate deliberative process to review the organizations functioning, efficiency and transparency and consider possible improvements, while bearing in mind the high priority attached to the successful conclusion of the DDA Doha Development Agenda negotiation (WTO, 2009). 41 However, the proposal was dropped from consideration following opposition from Bolivia, Cuba, Ecuador, Nicaragua and Venezuela ( ICTSD. 2009). An earlier communication submitted by India in summer 2009, entitled Strengthening the WTO, likewise remained without further consideration ( Deere-Birbeck, 2009). These missed opportunities further aggravate the dilemma of the WTO as political guidance becomes hampered at the very first stage ( Deere-Birbeck, 2009). If the secretariat assumed a more active role in preparing ministerial conferences and guiding towards processes as those called upon by the country coalition, initial opposition might be overcome. As a formal forum for discussing reform proposals continues to be missing, this could be the first step towards reform. 42 Beyond institutional reform, the current paralysis in the Doha Round is affecting the ability of the system to address pressing global challenges. Over the last 17 years, public perceptions of the organisations relevance and legitimacy have greatly depended on the degree to which it can credibly claim to be responding effectively to broader public policy demands in areas such as food security, environmental protection, labour standards and, more recently, the transition towards a low-carbon economy. However, the difficulty the WTO has experienced in bringing its troubled Doha Round talks to a successful conclusion is arguably hampering its ability to respond and adapt meaningfully to new public policy challenges. 43 From its inception in 1994 as an organisation outside the UN system, the WTO has consistently been obliged to demonstrate that its decision-making processes, rules and negotiating outcomes are consistent with broader public policy goals in the areas of health, the environment or development, to name but a few. While calls for greater policy coherence have often come from the governments that constitute the membership of the global trade body, they have also come from civil society groups, the media and even from other intergovernmental agencies concerned with the relationship between trade and public policy objectives. 9 Policies directed at ensuring food security certainly reach beyond the trade arena. Investment in (. ) 44 The evolution in the way in which food security concerns are addressed at the WTO can serve to illustrate the organisations attempt to take wider public policy goals into account.9 It also demonstrates the challenges that remain in establishing policy coherence with other global governance mechanisms, and in responding to the scale and ambition of the aspirations and commitments that governments have agreed to in the post-war period (United Nations General Assembly, 1948, art. 25 1 966, art. 11 2000, goal 1) (FAO, 1996, para. 2). 45 At the global level, evolving consumption patterns, combined with demographic changes, urbanisation and low agricultural productivity growth, are widely expected to mean that regional and international trade will play an increased role in many developing countries food security strategies. Combined with increased investment in agriculture, international trade mighthelp offset future climate-induced production decreases in certain regions, ensuring that local populations can purchase food that may be unavailable in sufficient quantities through domestic production. 10 Food security exists when all people, at all times, have physical and economic access to sufficie (. ) 46 Two years before the 1996 World Food Summit agreed on a landmark definition10 of food security that is still widely used and accepted today, the concept was mentioned in the preamble to the Agreement on Agriculture at the end of the Uruguay Round, and in some paragraphs within the text of the accord. These included provisions dealing with export prohibitions and restrictions (article 12), subsidies for public stockholding for food security purposes (Annex 2, para. 3) and a clause permitting exemptions to be made from market access binding and reduction commitments (Annex 5, para. 1d). However, while food security is also related to numerous other aspects of the agreement, such as subsidy reform or market access considerations, it is not explicitly mentioned anywhere else in the text. 11 See, for example, proposals from the developing country Like Minded Group (23 June 2000), GAGN (. ) 47 As governments concluded the Agreement on Agriculture, they also finalised the Marrakech Decision (WTO, 1999c) on least developed and net-food importing developing countries, supposedly intended to ensure that these countries would remain able to purchase food from external sources on reasonable terms and conditions. The decision has since been widely criticised by developing countries, who have argued that loopholes in the text prevent them from requiring developed countries and the international financial institutions to implement its provisions.11 Essentially, the decision characterises the challenge that net food-importing countries could face as a trade and balance-of-payments problem rather than a food security problem, and provides a fairly limited set of solutions centring mainly on the provision of food aid. 48 Arguably, the way in which food security concerns have been approached in the multilateral trading system has evolved considerably since the end of the Uruguay Round, along with the way in which other public policy goals have been treated. In the years running up to the 2001 Doha ministerial conference, developing country governments expressed growing concern that they were ill-equipped to implement the Uruguay Round agreements, that the provisions of these agreements undermined domestic food security, or as in the case of the Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) that they had signed on to texts which affected their food security without fully understanding the practical and legal implications that might result. In some cases, these concerns were also echoed by development agencies and campaign groups, farmers organisations, research centres, academic experts and the staff of various intergovernmental organisations. 12 Cuba, Dominican Republic, Honduras, Pakistan, Haiti, Nicaragua, Kenya, Uganda, Zimbabwe, Sri Lanka (. ) 13 India (15 January 2001), GAGNGW102, wto. orgenglishtratopeagricenegsbkgrnd02p (. ) 14 Domestic support measures that are exempt from reduction commitments on the basis that they cause (. ) 49 In the summer following the WTOs Seattle ministerial conference in 1999, a cross-regional group of 11 developing countries known as the Like-Minded Group submitted a proposal12 for a development box, under the built-in agenda of negotiations foreseen in article 20 of the Agreement on Agriculture. The sponsors called for a development box that would aim to increase food security and food accessibility by allowing developing countries to select which products would be disciplined under the rules of the Agreement on Agriculture allowing developing countries to re-evaluate and adjust their tariff levels provide greater flexibility for developing countries to use limited amounts of trade-distorting support under the de minimis provision (WTO, 1999a, art. 6.4) and allowing developing countries to use the special safeguard clause. Measures to reform developed country subsidies and tariffs were also included as part of the same proposal. The Indian government echoed many of these proposals in an early 2001 submission13 calling for the establishment of a food security box, which also contemplated measures to reform rules on green box subsidies.14 Several of the elements outlined in the development box proposal were later to appear, in modified form, in subsequent negotiating submissions and texts. 50 The Doha declaration launching a new round of trade talks dubbed the Doha Development Agenda by the WTO also made explicit reference to food security goals. It stated that developing countries would be accorded special and differential treatment so as to enable them to take account effectively of their development needs, including food security and rural development (WTO, 2001, para. 13). Such treatment was to be an integral part of all elements of the negotiations, the declaration said, in language that was to be echoed in a large number of negotiating proposals submitted in the years that were to follow. 15 Substantial improvements in market access reductions of, with a view to phasing out, all forms o (. ) 51 The dozens of proposals that invoked food security during the Doha Round, and in the years immediately before its launch, can be roughly divided into a handful of broad, non-exhaustive categories, largely reflecting the emphasis of the agriculture negotiations on four main areas15 : 52 On market access, many developing countries sought to be granted greater flexibility on tariff commitments, and access to an agricultural safeguard that would allow themselves to shield producers from the effects of import surges or price depressions. 16 A provision allowing developing countries to exempt some input and investment subsidies from reduc (. ) 53 Food security concerns were discussed in relation to trade-distorting support in general, but were also given particular attention in proposals for reform of the WTOs green box, and for maintaining or expanding article 6.2 of the Uruguay Round Agreement on Agriculture.16 54 The issue of food security also arose in negotiations on proposed new disciplines governing the provision of food aid, and in debates on export credits and other export competition issues. 55 Finally, importing countries in particular raised questions and concerns over food security in proposals on export restrictions (including export taxes and export prohibitions). 56 In each of these areas, different political constituencies and country grouping were active in seeking concessions. 17 See, for example, G-33 proposals: 1 June 2004 (JOB(04)65) 3 June 2005 (JOB(05)91) 12 Oct 2005 (. ) 57 On special products and the special safeguard mechanism, a group of import-sensitive developing countries that came to be known as the G-33 argued in favour of greater flexibility on market access disciplines, on the basis that this was needed to safeguard the livelihoods, food security and longer-term development of their rural populations, including large numbers of small-scale producers that would be ill-equipped to compete with industrialised (and often also subsidised) agriculture elsewhere in the world.17 Analysis by the Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO), the International Centre for Trade and Sustainable Development (ICTSD) and the South Centre including country level studies helped contribute to the evolution of countries negotiating positions on these issues (Mably, 2007 Wolfe, 2009 ICTSDFAO, 2007 Matthews, 2017). 18 See, for example, various exporting country proposals: 2 May 2006 (JOB(06)135) 3 May 2006 (JOB(0 (. ) 58 The G-33 proposed allowing developing countries to designate a limited set of products as special based on objective indicators of food security, livelihood security and rural development. Such indicators included, for example, the share of local income spent on a particular product, employment by product, productivity levels, rates of self-sufficiency, or the contribution of a product to local nutrition. Based on this country-specific analysis the tariffs of the selected products would then qualify for gentler reduction under the Doha Round, or would even be exempt from any cuts. The G-33, however, encountered opposition to their proposals from developed countries seeking greater access to developing country markets, such as the US, but also from exporting developing countries, such as Argentina, Paraguay and Uruguay.18 Controversy over the special safeguard mechanism played a s ignificant role in the breakdown of talks in July 2008 (ICTSD, 2008a). 59 Despite the disagreements in this area, the debate over special products in particular probably represents the most sophisticated attempt at defining food and livelihood security concerns in the WTO and how they relate to international trade. It is also symptomatic of how the discussion evolved over time in the trade body from a fairly narrow understanding of food security to a highly complex and differentiated approach based on indicators. 19 See African Group proposal, 20 Nov 2007 (JOB(02)187). 60 Food security concerns were also given particular attention in the review of the criteria for green box subsidies, as well as in the negotiations on domestic support more generally. The African Group (a group of developing countries that seeks reform of developed country agriculture), along with the G-20, has sought to expand the flexibility that the green box allows developing countries in being able to use domestic support to pursue national development goals.19 Among other things, these proposals would involve modifying the language on support for public stockholding for food security purposes so as to remove the existing requirement that developing countries count purchases from low-income or resource-poor producers towards their aggregate measure of support (AMS) an upper ceiling which would be reduced as part of the Doha Round negotiations. 61 In addition to proposals favouring greater flexibility for developing countries to subsidise their own agriculture sectors, two other main trends can be identified in the discussions on green box reform and in the debate over domestic support more generally (Hepburn and Bellmann, 2009). The first of these is the concern expressed by the G-2020 and by efficient agricultural exporters in the Cairns Group, which have argued that trade-distorting support undermines competitiveness and food security in countries that do not subsidise their agricultural sectors.21 These countries have also argued that green box programmes may be causing more than minimal trade distortion, and called for the criteria for these payments to be tightened.22 The other major trend is characterised by the proposals of countries with highly protected and heavily subsidised agricultural sectors, which have resisted such demands. These countries which include Japan23 and others in the G-10 coalition, as well as, to a lesser extent, the EU24 have instead historically called for greater flexibility to allow WTO members to address non-trade concerns, including food security. 25 See WTO (2005), para. 6. The text further specifies:On food aid, we reconfirm our commitment to m (. ) 26 6 March 2006 (TNAGGEN13). 27 25 Apr 2006 (JOB(06)122). 28 7 Apr 2006 (JOB(06)78). 62 Food security was also debated extensively in the negotiations over new rules on food aid. In exchange for agreeing, at the WTOs Hong Kong Ministerial in 2005, to the elimination of export subsidies, the EU had pressed trading partners to adopt disciplines on all export measures with equivalent effect including food aid.25 At the heart of the debate was the notion that in-kind food aid or practices such as monetisation have sometimes disrupted local food markets and affected local producers. While members agreed that a safe box would cover bona fide emergency situations, they also agreed to introduce rules that would prevent aid from undermining local producers in non-emergency situations. A proposal from the African and LDC groups26 formed the basis for negotiations, with further contributions from the European Community27 and the US28 the worlds major provider of in-kind food aid (ICTSD, 2006). 29 Cairns Group, 21 Dec 2000 (GAGNGW93) Japan, 15 Nov 2002 (JOB(02)164) Mauritius, 19 Nov 2002 (. ) 63 While the impact of export restrictions on food security has been a concern of various WTO members since the start of the Doha Round,29 debate and controversy over this issue has recently intensified, as two episodes of unusually high food prices and predictions of a long-term upward price trend for agricultural products increase the pressure on food importing countries, especially in the developing world (ICTSD, 2017, 2017b, c). While net-food-importing countries have drawn on analysis (FAO et al. 2017) by FAO staff and other experts to argue that export restrictions endanger food security by exacerbating shortages and volatility on world markets, exporting countries have thus far resisted any attempts to introduce more systemic disciplines in this area that go beyond the relatively limited disciplines set out in the Agreement on Agriculture or contemplated in the latest draft Doha agriculture accord. In part, this may be because of the role such measures play in supporting a strategy of enhancing value-addition in the exporting countries agriculture sector, and partly because of concerns that they could serve a useful role in responding to potential domestic food shortages. However, possibly more important is a more generalised reluctance on the part of exporting countries to make concessions in the absence of more far-reaching disciplines on trade distortions on the import side. 64 Despite the post-2008 stalemate in the WTOs Doha process, the same price trends and projections have helped to push food security back towards the top of the agenda in a number of political and policy-making processes, with the role of trade receiving some attention in this context. A series of high-level meetings the G-8s meeting in LAquila in 2008, the FAOs World Summit on Food Security in 2009 and the G-20 gathering of agriculture ministers in 2017 reflected the increased political importance being accorded to the question. However, while heads of state and ministers reaffirmed the importance of access to markets and pledged their commitment to raise agricultural productivity by boosting aid and investment, the WTO continues to be seen as the sole forum where concrete market access and subsidy commitments can be made. Even where agreement on trade-related measures has been reached, such as the G-20s June 2017 accord on exempting humanitarian food purchases from export restrictions, governments have recommended that further action be taken at the WTO (ICTSD, 2017a). Other trade-related issues such as biofuel subsidies have proven to be too controversial to be addressed meaningfully by the G-8 or G-20 (Tangermann, 2017), leaving their food security implications unresolved for the time being. 65 The establishment of the UNs High Level Task Force on the Global Food Security Crisis , the elaboration of its Comprehensive Framework of Action and the reform of the Committee on World Food Security (CWFS) were significant steps in the effort to improve global governance and enhance policy coherence in this area. The WTO, FAO and eight other relevant bodies also collaborated around the inter-agency report to the G-20 in the first half of 2017 (FAO et al. 2017). However, much more could still be done in this regard. Recent suggestions have included ensuring that the WTO Committee on Agriculture takes a more active role in reviewing food security issues related to trade, and strengthening the collaboration between the CWFS, the WTO, the World Bank and the Rome-based institutions (Ahmad, 2017). Reforming and improving the international governance framework is a necessary step towards overcoming current shortcomings on trade and food security, even though by itself it will not be sufficient to do so. 66 Measures to enhance policy coherence and to reform governance structures at the international level will, however, need to be accompanied by similar moves at the domestic level, especially in key countries. The disconnect between governance mechanisms responsible for development and aid, for the environment and for agricultural policy can mean that, for example, EU or US policies on farm subsidies may be at odds with policies pursued on related issues such as climate or poverty. Furthermore, to a great extent, the geopolitical tensions between countries and blocs that have thwarted progress on international trade issues are mirrored by similar tensions on climate change, food security and development issues more generally. Behind these lie configurations of domestic interests and political constituencies at the national and sub-national level. The shifting global economic landscape of the last decade has thrown up new opportunities and threats for different actors, in developed countries as well as in the so-called emerging countries of the developing world, and created new challenges for the worlds poorest people whether they live in the group of countries that the UN officially recognises as LDCs, or elsewhere. 67 Even among trade negotiators, there is a growing awareness that the multilateral trading system is proving increasingly incapable of demonstrating that it is flexible and adaptable enough to prove its relevance in a changing world. At the same time, negotiators are reluctant to abandon the investment that has been made in elaborating a package of farm trade disciplines that are perceived to go some way towards restructuring an agricultural trading system that has been heavily criticised for failing to deliver on a range of global public policy goals, including food security. Any decision to abandon the Doha talks, or place them in deep freeze, would arguably leave a large Doha-shaped hole: current patterns of trade-distorting support and tariff protection would remain unchanged, in addition to the new trade and food security challenges that are emerging. Until countries are able to resolve the growing contradictions between domestic policies on trade, food security, climate and international development, there is little prospect of achieving greater policy coherence in these areas at the global level. 68 The WTO is not what it used to be a decade or so ago. Many new developing countries have since joined, and shifts in the balance of global economic and political power have transformed the playing field. Accordingly, new needs and different expectations have emerged, including demands on the decision-making processes, and their fairness and transparency. As described above, modern global trade governance requires a careful balance between greater efficiency, legitimacy and inclusiveness. These objectives are not incompatible, but would require WTO members to move from essentially promoting their individual short-term mercantilist interests to developing a shared vision to effectively advance global public policy goals. Numerous proposals have been put forward to strengthen the multilateral trading system. But as for any intergovernmental institution, change must come, and be agreed to, from the inside. This calls for the establishment of an inclusive and bottom-up process, one that seeks input from all WTO members, as well as seeking submissions from the different actors in the international trade community. Only with such a process will ideas have a realistic chance to be considered, and be transformed into agents for strengthening the system. 69 Years of near-exclusive focus on the Doha Round have inhibited institutional evolution and even diminished some of the WTOs permanent, non-negotiating functions such as the work of the regular committees. Beyond the WTO negotiating function, there might be therefore merit in strengthening the work of the regular WTO committees. In the run-up to the 2009 Ministerial Conference, several such proposals were put on the table, notably by India.30 These covered a variety of issues such as the need to enhance the WTO trade information system by including data on non-tariff barriers monitor developments in regional trade agreements (RTAs) and develop non-binding best practice guidelines for negotiating new RTAs establish an omnibus legal system that would address all forms of preferential market access for LDCs in a coherent way address the increasing role of standards and standard-setting bodies in international trade. Many of these proposals are still relevant today. 70 Finally, in parallel with efforts to revive the Doha Round, members could undertake work on a number of pressing global challenges. These could include concerns around the trade dimension of food security, food prices and export restrictions the potential trade impacts of emerging domestic policies designed to combat climate change or highly controversial matters around exchange rate policies and current trade imbalances. This is not to say that the WTO should become the sole or even primary body to deal with these matters. Several other institutions such as the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC), FAO or IMF have indeed a major role to play in this area. The WTO, as the main organisation dealing with trade rules, should nevertheless contribute to addressing them insofar as they are linked to trade. Willingness to do so has already been expressed by a wide and cross-cutting segment of the WTO membership, but as a first step it might be more realistic to address these issues in a non-negotiating setting. In doing so, members could assess whether the WTO rule book is properly equipped to deal with emerging challenges or whether existing disciplines need to be clarified or amended. Existing institutional structures such as the Committee on Agriculture could be used for such an exercise. Precedents for doing so already exist. Singapore, for example, has recently made a submission to the regular session of the Committee on Trade and Environment to embark on work examining possible trade applications of border tax adjustment as a way to address competitiveness and carbon leakage concerns in climate change. Such an approach would enable the system to address challenges of the twenty-first century and prepare the ground for future negotiations when the political situation is ripe. Bibliography AFDB (African Development Bank), OECD (Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development), UNDP (United Nations Development Programme), UNECA (United Nations Economic Commission for Africa) (2017) African Economic Outlook 2017 (Paris: OECD). Ahmad, M. (2017) Improving the International Governance of Food Security and Trade (Geneva: International Centre for Trade and Sustainable Development). Anghie, A. (2005) Imperialism, Sovereignty and the Making of International Law (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). Consultative Board to the Director-General (2004) The Future of the WTO: Addressing Institutional Changes in the New Millennium (Geneva: World Trade Organization). Cottier, T. and M. Elsig (2009) Reforming the WTO: The Decisions-Making Triangle Re-Addressed . paper presented at the World Trade Forum, World Trade Institute, University of Bern. Cottier, T. and S. Takenoshita (2008) Decisions-Making and the Balance of Powers in WTO Negotiations: Towards Supplementary Weighted Voting, in Griller, S. (ed.) At the Crossroads: The World Trading System and the Doha Round (Vienna: Springer). Croome, J. (1995) Reshaping the World Trading System (Geneva: World Trade Organisation WTO). Deere-Birbeck, C. (2009) Momentum Builds for Discussion of Reform at WTO Ministerial Conference . Global Economic Governance Programmes blog, 20 November, globaleconomicgovernance. orgblog200911momentum-builds-for-discussion-on-wto-reform-at-wto-ministerial-conference (accessed on 27 September 2017). Deere-Birbeck, C. and C. Monagle (2009) Strengthening Multilateralism: A Mapping of Selected Proposals on WTO Reform and Improvements in Global Trade Governance . discussion draft (GenevaOxford: ICTSD and Global Economic Governance Programme). Elsig, M. (2008) The World Trade Organization at Work: Performance in a Member-Driven Milieu . paper presented at the Annual Convention of the International Studies Association, New York, 1518 February. Elsig, M. (2009) WTO Decisions-Making: Can We Get a Little Help from the Secretariat and the Critical Mass, in Steger, D. P. (ed.) Redesigning the World Trade Organization for the Twenty-first Century (Waterloo: Wilfrid Laurier University Press). FAO (Food and Agriculture Organization), IFAD (International Fund for Agricultural Development), IMF (International Monetary Fund), OECD (Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development), UNCTAD (United Nations Conference on Trade and Development), WFP (World Food Programme), World Bank, WTO, IFPRI (International Food Policy Research Institute) and the UN HLTF (High-Level Task Force) (2017) Price Volatility in Food and Agricultural Markets: Policy Responses (Rome: FAO), fao. orgfileadmintemplatesestVolatilityInteragencyReporttotheG20onFoodPriceVolatility. pdf (accessed on 27 September 2017). FAO (1996) Rome Declaration on Food Security and World Food Summit Plan of Action . W3613 (Rome: FAO). Harbinson, S. (2009) The Doha Round: Death-Defying Agenda or Dont Do it Again . ECIPE (European Centre for International Political Economy) Working Paper no. 10 (Brussels: ECIPE). Hepburn, J. and C. Bellmann (2009) Doha Round Negotiations on the Green Box and Beyond, in Melndez-Ortiz, R. C. Bellmann and J. Hepburn (eds.) Agricultural Subsidies in the WTO Green Box: Ensuring Coherence with Sustainable Development Goals (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). Hufbauer, G. (2005) Inconsistencies Between Diagnosis and Treatment, Journal of International Economic Law ,8(2), pp. 2917. ICTSD (International Centre for Trade and Sustainable Development) (2006) EU Food Aid Paper Proposes Strict Disciplines to Prevent Commercial Displacement, Bridges Weekly . 10(15), 3 May, ictsd. orginewsbridgesweekly7394 (accessed on 27 September 2017). ICTSD (2008a) Agricultural Safeguard Controversy Triggers Breakdown in Doha Round Talks, Bridges Weekly . 12(27), 7 August, ictsd. orginewsbridgesweekly18034 (accessed on 27 September 2017). ICTSD ( 2008b) Concern Grows over New IP Agreement, Bridges Monthly . 12(5), November, ictsd. orgdownloadsbridgesbridges12-5.pdf (accessed on 27 September 2017). ICTSD (2009) WTO Ministerial Conference Opens in Geneva: Expect No Surprises . Bridges Daily Update, 30 November, ictsd. orgiwtogenevadaily-updates-2009geneva-2009-bridges-daily-updates62462 (accessed on 27 September 2017). ICTSD (2017) Under Threat of Higher Food Prices, WTO Members Debate Export Restrictions, Subsidies, Bridges Weekly . 14(41), 24 November, ictsd. orginewsbridgesweekly96974 (accessed on 27 September 2017). ICTSD (2017a) G-20 Agriculture Ministers Unveil Plan to Tackle High Food Prices, Bridges Weekly . 15(24), 29 June, ictsd. orginewsbridgesweekly109720 (accessed on 27 September 2017). ICTSD (2017b) OECD, FAO: No End for High Food Prices in Upcoming Decade, Bridges Weekly . 15(23), 22 June, ictsd. orginewsbridgesweekly109150 (accessed on 27 September 2017). ICTSD (2017c) Agricultural Export Restrictions Spark Controversy at the WTO, Bridges Weekly . 15(12), 6 April, ictsd. orginewsbridgesweekly103579 (accessed on 27 September 2017). ICTSD ( 2017d) Tensions Build over Chinese Rare Earth Quotas, Bridges Trade BioRes . 11(16), 25 July, ictsd. orginewsbiores111203 (accessed on 27 September 2017). ICTSDFAO (2007) Indicators for the Selection of Agricultural Special Products: Some Empirical Evidence (Geneva: ICTSD). Ismail, F. and B. Vickers (2017) Towards Fair and Inclusive Decision-Making in WTO Negotiations, in Deere-Birbeck, C. (ed.) Making Global Trade Governance Work for Development (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). Jackson, J. (2001) The WTO Constitution and Proposed Reforms: Seven Mantras Revisited, Journal of International Economic Law . 4(1), pp. 6778. Keohane, R. and J. Nye (2000) Between Centralization and Fragmentation: The Club Model of Multilateral Cooperation and Problems of Democratic Legitimacy . paper presented at the American Political Science Convention, Washington, DC, 31 August3 September. Lamy, P. (2003) After Cancun . Statements by Pascal Lamy, EU Trade Commissioner, at the Press Conference Closing the 5th WTO Ministerial Conference in Cancun on, 14 September. eurunion. orgnewspress20032003057.htm (accessed on 27 September 2017). Low, P. (2009) WTO Decision Making for the Future . paper presented at Thinking Ahead on International Trade (TAIT) Inaugural Conference, Geneva, 1718 September. Mably, P. (2007) The Role of Research on Trade Policy Changes Affecting the Developing World: Group of 33 Influence at the World Trade Organization . Latin American Trade Network Working Paper no. 77 (Buenos Aires: Latin American School of Social Sciences), latn. org. arwebwp-contentuploads201706wp-77-Mably. pdf (accessed on 27 September 2017). Matthews, A. (2017) The Impact of WTO Agricultural Trade Rules on Food Security and Development: An Examination of Proposed Additional Flexibilities for Developing Countries . IIIS (Institute for International Integration Studies) Discussion Paper no. 371 (Dublin: IIIS, Trinity College), tcd. ieiiisdocumentsdiscussionpdfsiiisdp371.pdf (accessed on 27 September 2017). Mayer, J. (2017) Structural Change, Global Imbalances, and Employment in the Least Developed Countries . Policy Brief no. 1 (Geneva: ICTSD). Oxfam (2002) Rigged Rules and Double Standards. Trade, Globalisation and the Fight Against Poverty (BrusselsGenevaNew YorkWashington: Oxfam), maketradefairassetsenglishreportenglish. pdf (accessed on 27 September 2017). Pauwelyn, J. (2005) The Sutherland Report: A Missed Opportunity for Genuine Debate on Trade, Globalization and Reforming the WTO, Journal of International Economic Law . 8(2), pp. 32946. Rodriguez Mendoza, M. and M. Wilke (2017) Revisiting the Single Undertaking: Towards a More Balanced Approach to WTO Negotiations, in Deere-Birbeck C. (ed.) (2017) Making Global Trade Governance Work for Development (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). Rolland, S. (2017) Redesigning the Negotiation Process at the WTO, Journal of International Economic Law . 13(65), pp. 65110. Steger, D. (ed.) (2009) Why Institutional Reform of the WTO is Necessary, in Redesigning the World Trade Organization (Waterloo: Wilfrid Laurier University Press), pp. 311. Steinberg, R. (2002) In the Shadow of Law or Power Consensus-Based Bargaining and Outcomes at the GATTWTO, International Organizations . 56(2), pp. 33974. UNCTAD (2017) World Investment Report 2017, Non-Equity Modes of International Production and Development (Geneva: UNCTAD). United Nations General Assembly (2000) United Nations Millennium Declaration . ARES552 (New York: United Nations). United Nations General Assembly (1948) Universal Declaration of Human Rights (New York: United Nations), un. orgendocumentsudhr (accessed on 27 September 2017). United Nations General Assembly (1966) International Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights (New York: United Nations), www2.ohchr. orgenglishlawcescr. htm (accessed on 27 September 2017). Van Grasstek, C. and P. Sauv (2006) The Consistency of WTO Rules: Can the Single Undertaking be Squared with Variable Geometry, Journal of International Economic Law . 9(4), pp. 83764. Warwick Commission (2007) The Multilateral Trade Regime: Which Way Forward (Coventry: Warwick University). Wolfe, R. (2009) The Special Safeguard Fiasco in the WTO: The Perils of Inadequate Analysis and Negotiation, World Trade Review . 8(4), pp. 51744. WTO (1999a) Agreement on Agriculture, in The Legal Texts: The Results of the Uruguay Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). WTO (1999b) Decision on the Application and Review of the Understanding on Rules and Procedures Governing the Settlement of Disputes, in The Legal Texts: The Results of the Uruguay Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). Warwick Commission (2007) The Multilateral Trade Regime: Which Way Forward (Coventry: The University of Warwick). WTO (1999c) Decision on Measures Concerning the Possible Negative Effects of the Reform Programme on Least-Developed and Net Food-Importing Developing Countries, in The Legal Texts: The Results of the Uruguay Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). WTO (1999d) Marrakech Agreement Establishing the World Trade Organization, in The Legal Texts: The Results of the Uruguay Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). WTO (2001) Doha Ministerial Declaration . WTMIN(01)DEC1 (Doha: WTO). WTO (2005) Hong Kong Ministerial Declaration . WTMIN(05)DEC (Hong Kong: WTO). WTO (2009) Strengthening the WTO . WTMIN(09)W1, Communication from Australia, Brazil, Canada, China, Hong Kong China, European Communities, India, Japan, Korea, Malaysia, Mauritius, Mexico, Norway, South Africa, Switzerland, Turkey, United States and Uruguay (Geneva: WTO). WTO (2017a) World Trade Report 2017. The WTO and Preferential Trade Agreements: From Co-existence to Coherence (Geneva: WTO). WTO (2017b) Quarterly World Merchandise Trade by Region and Selected Economies (Geneva: WTO), wto. orgenglishresestatisequarterlyworldexpe. htm (accessed on 8 November 2017). 1 The Warwick Report . for example, provides one of the most notable and comprehensive stock-taking exercises produced by non-governmental experts (Warwick Commission, 2007). Another critical milestone in this debate was the report commissioned in 2003 by Dr Supachai Panitchpakdi, then Director General of the World Trade Organization (WTO), to a panel of experts chaired by the former Director General of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), Peter Sutherland, on The Future of the WTO: Addressing Institutional Challenges in the New Millennium. Despite its comprehensive analysis and concrete recommendations, the Sutherland Report was, however, criticised as a defence of the status quo . produced by insiders, thus lacking novel approaches (Hufbauer, 2005 Pauwelyn, 2005). As such it did not provide the necessary impetus to initiate a structured discussion among members. 2 When governments launched the Uruguay Round of trade negotiations under the GATT in 1986, the declared aim was not to establish a standing global organisation on trade governance. What later became the WTO, only emerged over the last few months of the almost eight years lasting negotiations. When members realised that the trade package to be presented at the end of the negotiation round would include new areas such as intellectual property rights and services, the need arose to discuss processes and structures that would ensure the coherence of these different agreements. The decision to establish the WTO finally stemmed from that discussion and other related considerations in the negotiation Group on the Functioning of the GATT (FOGS). Since no systemic, long-term negotiations had taken place on a potential international organisation, most agreements (with the exception of the Dispute Settlement Understanding (DSU) which had been revised completely during the Uruguay Round) thus replicate the principles that have served that GATT for the last five decades. Moreover, when members launched the ongoing Doha Round they referred back to the negotiation principles used during the Uruguay Round, namely the principles of consensus and single undertaking. See Rodriguez Mendoza and Wilke (2017). 3 The consensus principle dates back to the International Trade Organization (ITO) and with it the early beginnings of the GATT. See Ismail and Vickers (2017). 4 With the exception of the improvements and clarifications of the DSU, the conduct, conclusion and entry into force of the outcome of the negotiations shall be treated as parts of a single undertaking. However, agreements reached at an early stage may be implemented on a provisional or a definitive basis. Early agreements shall be taken into account in assessing the overall balance of the negotiations (WTO, 2001, para. 47). 5 Note that weighted voting at the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund (IMF) is based on the level of a countrys financial contribution to the organisations budget. Currently the United States holds roughly 17 per cent of the votes, with the G-7 holding a total of 45 per cent. WTO-related proposals certainly differ from this, yet there are important lessons to be learnt from the World Banks and IMFs experience with power-based voting. 6 The agreements and associated legal instruments included in Annex 4 (hereinafter referred to as Plurilateral Trade Agreements) are also part of this Agreement for those Members that have accepted them, and are binding on those Members. The Plurilateral Trade Agreements do not create either obligations or rights for Members that have not accepted them (WTO, 1999d, Article II:3). 7 See for instance the 2003 Memorandum on the Need to Improve Internal Transparency and Participation in the WTO by the Third World Network, Oxfam International, Public Services International, World Wildlife Fund International, The Center for International Environmental Law, Focus on the Global South, The Institute for Agriculture and Trade Policy, The Africa Trade Network, The International General and Trade Network, and the Tebtebba International Centre for Indigenous Peoples Rights, 13 July 2003. 8 For instance, during the 7th Ministerial Conference in 2009, the delegation of Uruguay called upon the WTO members to not confuse the Ministerial with various kinds of negotiation sessions. There would be no justification for continuing to postpone the regular revocation of the topmost body of the WTO, particularly in the current world economic and trade environment, which requires international cooperation, direct political involvement at the multilateral level, and strong credible institutions (WTO, 2009). 9 Policies directed at ensuring food security certainly reach beyond the trade arena. Investment in the agriculture sector, land rights and access to water and other natural resources are of equal importance in this context. However, the following discussion will be limited to the interface of the multilateral trading system and food security. 10 Food security exists when all people, at all times, have physical and economic access to sufficient, safe and nutritious food to meet their dietary needs and food preferences for an active and healthy life(FAO, 1996). 11 See, for example, proposals from the developing country Like Minded Group (23 June 2000), GAGNGW13 Kenya (12 March 2001), GAGNGW136 and Small Island Developing States (29 December 2000), GAGNGW97, wto. orgenglishtratopeagricenegsbkgrnd02props1e. htm (accessed on 27 September 2017). 12 Cuba, Dominican Republic, Honduras, Pakistan, Haiti, Nicaragua, Kenya, Uganda, Zimbabwe, Sri Lanka and El Salvador (23 June 2000), GAGNGW13, wto. orgenglishtratopeagricenegsbkgrnd02props1e. htm (accessed on 27 September 2017). 14 Domestic support measures that are exempt from reduction commitments on the basis that they cause not more than minimal distortion of trade or production, set out in Annex 2 of the Agreement on Agriculture. 15 Substantial improvements in market access reductions of, with a view to phasing out, all forms of export subsidies and substantial reductions in trade-distorting domestic support (WTO, 2001, para. 13). 16 A provision allowing developing countries to exempt some input and investment subsidies from reduction commitments. 17 See, for example, G-33 proposals: 1 June 2004 (JOB(04)65) 3 June 2005 (JOB(05)91) 12 Oct 2005 (JOB(05)230) 22 Nov 2005 (JOB(05)304) 22 Nov 2005 (JOB(05)303) 11 May 2006 (JOB(06)143) 7 June 2006 (JOB(06)173) 16 June 2006 (JOB(06)189Rev.1) 28 Mar 2007 (JOB(07)35) 3 June 2008 (JOB(08)47) 28 Jan 2017 (TNAGGEN30). 18 See, for example, various exporting country proposals: 2 May 2006 (JOB(06)135) 3 May 2006 (JOB(06)137) 20 February 2008 (JOB(08)6) 8 April 2008 (JOB(08)24). 19 See African Group proposal, 20 Nov 2007 (JOB(02)187). 20 16 May 2006 (JOB(06)145). 21 Arguably, civil society organisations also played an important role in highlighting some of these connections. See, for example, Oxfam (2002). 22 See, for example, proposals dated 27 Sept 2002: Cairns Group (JOB(02)132) and Canada (JOB(02)131). 25 See WTO (2005), para. 6. The text further specifies:On food aid, we reconfirm our commitment to maintain an adequate level and to take into account the interests of food aid recipient countries. To this end, a safe box for bona fide food aid will be provided to ensure that there is no unintended impediment to dealing with emergency situations. Beyond that, we will ensure elimination of commercial displacement. To this end, we will agree effective disciplines on in-kind food aid, monetization and re-exports so that there can be no loop-hole for continuing export subsidization. 26 6 March 2006 (TNAGGEN13). 27 25 Apr 2006 (JOB(06)122). 28 7 Apr 2006 (JOB(06)78). 29 Cairns Group, 21 Dec 2000 (GAGNGW93) Japan, 15 Nov 2002 (JOB(02)164) Mauritius, 19 Nov 2002 (JOB(02)182) Cuba, 20 Jan 2003 (JOB(02)190Corr.1 Korea, 18 Dec 2002 (JOB(02)220) Japan, 28 Feb 2003 (JOB(03)41 G-20), 18 May 2006 (JOB(06)147) Japan and Switzerland, 30 Apr 2008 (JOB(08)34) Net Food-Importing Developing Countries, 6 Apr 2017 (JOBAG18). List of illustrations References Electronic reference Christophe Bellmann. Jonathan Hepburn and Marie Wilke . The Challenges Facing the Multilateral Trading System in Addressing Global Public Policy Objectives , International Development Policy Revue internationale de politique de dveloppement Online, 3 2017, Online since 27 February 2017, connection on 08 March 2017. URL. poldev. revues. org1012 DOI. 10.4000poldev.1012 About the authors Programmes Director at the International Centre for Trade and Sustainable Development (ICTSD). He has previously worked for the Swiss Coalition of Development Organisations. He also was a Research Associate a t the Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean in Santiago. By this author Published in International Development Policy Revue internationale de politique de dveloppement . 6.2 2018 Published in International Development Policy Revue internationale de politique de dveloppement . 5.2 2017 Published in International Development Policy Revue internationale de politique de dveloppement . 2 2017 Published in International Development Policy Revue internationale de politique de dveloppement . 1 2017 Agriculture Programme Manager, International Centre for Trade and Sustainable Development (ICTSD). Before joining ICTSD, he represented Oxfam International at the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund (IMF) in Washington, and led Oxfams global campaign on aid, debt and the Millennium Development Goals. He previously worked on trade, development and human rights issues at the Quaker United Nations Office in Geneva. By this author Published in International Development Policy Revue internationale de politique de dveloppement . 2 2017 International Trade Law Programme Officer at the International Centre for Trade and Sustainable Development (ICTSD). Previously she worked for the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) and for the German Federal Ministry of Economics and Technology. She holds a law degree from Hanse Law School and an LLM in Public International Law from Helsinki University (summa cum laude). Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial 3.0 Unported License.
Comments
Post a Comment